• Nenhum resultado encontrado

More General Credibility Models

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Share "More General Credibility Models"

Copied!
6
0
0

Texto

(1)

More General Credibility Models

Virginia ATANASIU

Department of Mathematics, Academy of Economic Studies e-mail: virginia_atanasiu@yahoo.com

This communication gives some extensions of the original Bühlmann model. The paper is devoted to semi-linear credibility, where one examines functions of the random variables representing claim amounts, rather than the claim amounts themselves. The main purpose of semi-linear credibility theory is the estimation of μ0

( )

θ =E

[

f0

(

Xt+1

)

θ

]

(the net premium for a contract with risk parameter: θ) by a linear combination of given functions of the observ-able variobserv-ables: X

(

X1,X2,...,Xt

' =

)

. So the estimators mainly considered here are linear functions of several functions of the observable random variables. The approxi-mation to

n

f f f1, 2,...,

( )

θ

μ0 based on prescribed approximating functions leads to the opti-mal non-homogeneous linearized estimator for the semi-linear credibility model. Also we dis-cuss the case when taking for all:

n

f f f1, 2,...,

f

fp = p, try to find the optimal function . It should be noted that the approximation to

f

( )

θ

μ0 based on a unique optimal approximating function is always better than the one furnished in the semi-linear credibility model based on pre-scribed approximating functions: . The usefulness of the latter approximation is that it is easy to apply, since it is sufficient to know estimates for the structural parameters appearing in the credibility factors. From this reason we give some unbiased estimators for the structure parameters. For this purpose we embed the contract in a collective of contracts, all providing independent information on the structure distribution. We close this paper by giving the semi-linear hierarchical model used in the applications chapter.

f

n

f f f1, 2,...,

Mathematics Subject Classification: 62P05.

Keywords: contracts, unbiased estimators, structure parameters, several approximating func-tions, semi-linear credibility theory, unique optimal function, parameter estimation, hierar-chical semi-linear credibility theory.

ntroduction In

credi

this article we first give the semi-linear bility model (see Section 1), which in-volves only one isolated contract. Our prob-lem (from Section1) is the estimation of

( )

θ

[

(

)

θ

]

μ0 =E f0 Xt+1 (the net premium for a

contract with risk parameter:

(

X X Xt

)

X' = 1, 2,..., . So our problem (from Section 1) is the determination of the linear combination of 1 and the random variables:

( )

r p X

f , p=1,n, r =1,t closest to

( )

θ

[

(

)

θ

]

μ0 =E f0 Xt+1 in the least squares

sense, where θ is the structure variable. The solution of this problem:

θ) by a linear combination of given functions

of the observable variables:

n

f f f1, 2,...,

( )

( )

⎪⎭ ⎪ ⎬ ⎫

⎪⎩ ⎪ ⎨ ⎧

⎥ ⎦ ⎤ ⎢

⎣ ⎡

∑∑

= =

2

1 1 0

0 ,

0

n

p t

r

r p pr f X

E

Min μ θ α

α

α −α − , where: α =

( )

αpr p,r, is the optimal non-homogeneous linearized

estimator (namely the semi-linear credibility result). In Section 2 we discuss the case when taking fp = f for all: p, try to find

the unique optimal function . It should be noted that the approximation to

I

f

( )

μ θ0

f

(2)

the semi-linear credibility model based on prescribed approximating functions:

. The usefulness of the latter ap-proximation is that it is easy to apply, since it is sufficient to know estimates for the struc-tural parameters: , (with

n

f f f1, 2,...,

pq

a bpq p,

q =0,n) appearing in the credibility factors (where

p

z p=1,n). To obtain estimates for these structure parameters from the semi-linear credibility model, in Section 3 we em-bed the contract in a collective of contracts, all providing independent information on the structure distribution. We close this paper by giving the semi-linear hierarchical model used in the applications chapter (see Section 4).

Section 1 (The approximation to μ0

( )

θ

based on prescribed approximating func-tions: f1, f2,...,fn)

In this section, we consider one contract with unknown and fixed risk parameter: θ, during a period of t years. The yearly claim amounts are denoted by: . The risk parameter

t

X X1,...,

θ is supposed to be drawn from some structure distribution function: U

( )

⋅ . It is assumed that, for given: θ, the claims are conditionally independent and identically dis-tributed (conditionally i.i.d.) with known common distribution function FXθ

( )

x,θ . The random variables are observable,

and the random variable is considered as being not (yet) observable. We assume that:

t

X X1,...,

1

+

t

X

( )

r p X

f , p=0,n, r=1,t+1 have finite variance. For: , we take the function of

we want to forecast.

0 f

1

+

t

X

We use the notation:

( )

θ

[

( )

θ

]

μp =E fp Xr | (1.1)

(

p=0,n;r=1,t+1

)

This expression does not depend on r.

We define the following structure parameters:

( )

[

p

]

{

[

p

( )

r

]

}

[

p

( )

r

]

p E E E f X E f X

m = μ θ = |θ = (1.2),

( ) ( )

[

]

{

p r , q r

}

pq ECov f X f X

a = (1.3),

( ) ( )

[

μp θ μq θ

]

pq Cov

b = , (1.4),

( ) ( )

[

p r q r

]

pq Cov f X f X

c = , (1.5),

( ) ( )

[

p r μq θ

]

pq Cov f X

d = , (1.6),

for: p, q=0,nr =1,t+1. These expres-sions do not depend on: r =1,t+1. The structure parameters are connected by the fol-lowing relations:

pq pq pq a b

c = + (1.7),

pq pq b

d = (1.8),

for: p,q =0,n. This follows from the covari-ance relations obtained in the probability the-ory where they are very well-known. Just as in the case of considering linear combina-tions of the observable variables themselves,

we can also obtain non-homogeneous credi-bility estimates, taking as estimators the class of linear combinations of given functions of the observable variables, as shown in the fol-lowing theorem:

Theorem 1.1 (Optimal non-homogeneous lin-earized estimators)

The linear combination of 1 and the random variables fp

( )

Xr ,p=1,n;r=1,t closest to

( )

θ

[

(

)

θ

]

μ0 =E f0 Xt+1 | and to f0

(

Xt+1

)

in the least squares sense equals:

( )

∑ ∑

=

= =

− +

= n

p

p p n

p t

r

r p

p f X m z m

t z M

1 0 1 1

1

(3)

where z1,z2,...,zn is a solution to the linear system of equations:

( )

[

]

p q

n

p

pq

pq t d z td

c 0

1

1 =

− +

=

(q=1,n) (1.10)

or to the equivalent linear system of equations:

(

)

p q

n

p

pq

pq tb z tb

a 0

1

= +

=

(q=1,n) (1.11)

Proof: we have to examine the solution of the problem:

( )

( )

⎪⎭ ⎪ ⎬ ⎫

⎪⎩ ⎪ ⎨ ⎧

⎥ ⎦ ⎤ ⎢

⎣ ⎡

∑∑

= =

2

1 1 0

0 ,

0

n

p t

r

r p pr f X

E

Min μ θ α α

α

α (1.12)

Taking the derivative with respect to α0 gives:

( )

[

]

[

( )

]

0

1 1

0 θ α α

μ −

∑∑

=

= = p r

n

p t

r

prE f X

E , or:

∑∑

. Inserting this expression for

= =

= n

p t

r

p prm

m

1 1 0

0 α

α

0

α into (1.12) leads to the following problem:

( )

(

( )

⎪⎭ ⎪ ⎬ ⎫

⎪⎩ ⎪ ⎨ ⎧

⎥ ⎦ ⎤ ⎢

⎣ ⎡

− −

∑∑

= =

2

1 1 0

0

n

p t

r

p r p

pr f X m

m E

Min μ θ α

α

)

(1.13)

On putting the derivatives with respect to αqr' equal to zero, we get the following system of equations (q=1,n; r'=1,t):

( ) ( )

[

]

∑∑

[

( ) ( )

= =

= n

p t

r

r q r p pr

r

q X Cov f X f X

f Cov

1 1

' '

0 θ , α ,

μ

]

(1.14)

Because of the symmetry in time clearly:

p pt p

p α α α

α 1 = 2 =...= = , so using the co-variance results, for q=1,n this system of equations can be written as:

( )

[

=

− + = n

p

pq pq

p

q c t d

b

1

0 α 1

]

(1.15)

Now (1.15) and (1.13) lead to (1.9) with:

t zp

p =

α , p =1,n.

Section 2 (The approximationto μ0

( )

θ based on a unique optimal approximating function: f )

The estimator M for μ0

( )

θ of Theorem 1.1

can be displayed as:

( )

X f

(

Xt

f

M = 1 +...+

)

(2.1), where:

( )

( )

= =

− +

= n

p

p p n

p p

p z m

t m t x f z t x f

1 0 1

1 1 1

.

Let us forget now about this structure of and look for any function such that (2.1) is closest to:

f f

( )

θ

μ0 . If are considered only

functions f such that f

( )

X1 has finite vari-ance, then the optimal approximating func-tion f results from the following theorem:

Theorem 2.1 (Optimal approximating func-tion)

( )

X f

( )

Xt

f 1 +...+ is closest to μ0

( )

θ and to

(

1

)

0 Xt+

f in the least squares sense, if and only if f is a solution of the equation:

( ) ( ) ( )

X1 + t−1E

[

f X2 X1

]

E

[

f0

( )

X2 X1

]

≡0

f

(2.2) Proof: we have to solve the following mini-mization problem:

(

) ( )

( )

[

]

{

2

}

1 1

0 t ... t

g E f X g X g X

Min + − − − (2.3)

Suppose that denotes the solution to this problem, then we consider:

f

( )

X f

( )

X h

( )

X

g = +α , with arbitrary, like in variational calculus. Let:

( )

(4)

( )

{

[

(

) ( )

( )

( )

( )

]

2

}

1

1 1

0 Xt f X ... f Xt h X ... h Xt

f

E α α

α

ϕ = + − − − − − − (2.4)

Clearly for f to be optimal, ϕ'

( )

0 =0, so for every choice of h:

(

) ( )

( )

[

]

[

( )

( )

{

f0 Xt+1f X1 −...− f Xt h X1 +...+h Xt

]

}

=0

E (2.5),

must hold. This can be rewritten as:

( ) ( )

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

[

tf0 X2 h X1tf X1 h X1t t−1 f X2 h X1

]

=0

E (2.6),

or:

( )

{

( ) ( ) ( )

[

]

[

( )

]

}

[

h X1f X1t−1E f X2 X1 +E f0 X2 X1

]

=0

E (2.7)

Because this equation has to be satisfied for every choice of the function one obtains, the expression in brackets in (2.7) must be identical to zero, which proves (2.2).

h

An application of Theorem 2.1:

If can only take the values

and

1 1,...,Xt+

X

n

,..., 1 ,

0 pqr =P

[

X1 =q,X2 =r

]

for: q,

n

r =0, , then f

( )

X1 +...+ f

(

Xt

)

is closest to μ0

( )

θ and to f0

(

Xt+1

)

in the least squares sense, if and only if for q=0,n, f

( )

q is a solution of the linear system:

( )

( )

( )

( )

qr n

r n

r

qr n

r

qr t f r p f r p

p q

f

= =

=

= −

+

0 0 0

0

1 (2.8)

Indeed:

( )

(

( )

)

( )

⎟⎟ ⎟

⎠ ⎞

⎜⎜ ⎜

⎝ ⎛ = ⎟⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜⎜

⎝ ⎛

=

=

n

r qr

p q f

q X P

q f X

f

0 1

1 : , q=0,n;

[

( )

]

=

( )

(

= =

=

1 2

0 1

2 X f r P X r X

X f E

n

r

)

( )

= =

=

= n

r qr qr n

r

p p r f q

0 0

;

[

( )

]

( )

(

)

( )

= =

=

= = =

= n

r qr qr n

r n

r

p p r f q

X r X P r f X

X f E

0 0

0 1

2 0

0 1

2

0 .

Inserting these expressions for: f

( )

X1 ,

( )

[

f X2 X1

]

E and E

[

f0

( )

X2 X1

]

into (2.2) leads to (2.8).

Section 3 (Parameter estimation)

It should be noted that the approximation to

( )

θ

μ0 based on a unique optimal approxi-mating function is always better than the one furnished in Section 1 based on

pre-scribed approximating functions: . The usefulness of the latter

ap-proximation is that it is easy to apply, since it is sufficient to know estimates for the struc-tural parameters , (with

f

n

f f f1, 2,...,

pq

a bpq p, q =0,n) appearing in the credibility factors zp (where

n

p=1, ). From this reason we give some un-biased estimators for the structure

parame-ters. For this purpose we consider con-tracts,

k

k

j=1, , and independent and

identically distributed vectors

k

(

≥2

)

(

j,X j

)

(

j,Xj1,...,Xjt

)

' θ

θ = , for j=1,k. The contract indexed j is a random vector consist-ing of a random structure parameter θj and observations: Xj1,...,Xjt, where j=1,k. For every contract j =1,k and for θj fixed, the variables: are conditionally

inde-pendent and identically distributed. jt

j X

X 1,...,

Theorem 3.1 (Unbiased estimators for the structure parameters)

Let:

∑∑

= =

=

= k

j

jr t

r p p

p f X

kt X kt m

1 1 ..

^

) ( 1

1

(3.1)

⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜

⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜

=

∑∑

= =

q j q

jr k

j t

r

p j p

jr

pq X

t X X t X t

k

a .

1 1

.

^ 1 1

) 1 (

1

(5)

t a X kt X t X kt X t k

b qj q pq

k j p p j pq ^ .. . 1 .. .

^ 1 1 1 1

1 1 ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ − =

= (3.3),

, then: , , , where: , ,

, , with

p p m

m

E ⎟=

⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ ^ pq pq a a

E ⎟=

⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ ^ pq pq b b

E ⎟=

⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ ^

= = t r p jr p j X X 1 .

= = t r q jr q j X X 1 .

∑∑

= = = k j t r p jr p X X 1 1 ..

∑∑

= = = k j t r q jr q X X 1 1

.. p

( )

jr

p

jr f X

X = , (j=1,k and r=1,t),

( )

jr

q q

jr f X

X = , (j =1,k and r=1,t), for p, q=0,n, such that p<q.

Proof: note that the usual definitions of the structure parameters apply, with θj replacing θ

and Xjr replacing Xr so: ⎟=

[

( )

]

= = =

⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛

p r j p r j jr p p m kt kt m kt X f E kt m E , ,

^ 1 1

p m ;

( )

[

(

)

( ) ( )

( )

⎟⎠− ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ − ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ − + − = ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝

q

j p jr q j p jr q jr p jr r j q jr p jr pq X t E X E X t X Cov X E X E X X Cov t k a

E . .

,

^ 1 1

, ,

1 1

( )

q jr p j q jr p

j X E X

t E X X t Cov ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ − ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ − . . 1 , 1

( )

− ⋅ = ⎥ ⎦ ⎤ ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ + ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ + 1 1 1 1 1 , 1 . . . . t k X t E X t E X t X t

Cov jp qj jp qj

(

)

⎥ ⎦ ⎤ ⎢ ⎣ ⎡ + ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ + + − ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ + − − ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ + − + + ⋅ r j q p pq pq q p pq pq q p pq pq q p pq

pq a b m m

t m m b a t m m b a t m m b a , 1 1 1 =

( )

( )

( )

pq pq

r j

pq pq pq

pq a a

t t kt t k b a t b a t k = − − = ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ +

1 1 1 1 1 1 , ; ⋅ ⎣ ⎡ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ − = ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛

j pq t Cov k b E 1 1 1 ^ , 1 1 1 1 , 1 1 1 1 , . . . . .. . .. .. . p q p j q p j q j p j q j p j X kt Cov X kt E X t E X kt X t Cov X t E X t E X t X ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ − ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ − ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ − ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ + ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⋅ = − ⎥ ⎦ ⎤ ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ + ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ + ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ − ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ t a X kt E X kt E X kt X kt Cov X t E X kt E X t pq q p q p q j p q

j. .. . .. .. .. ..

1 1 1 , 1 1 1 1 , ⋅ −1 1 k + ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ + − ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ + − − ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ + − + ⎢ ⎣ ⎡ ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ +

p q pq pq p q pq pq p q pq

j pq pq a kt m m b k a kt m m b k a kt m m b a t 1 1 1 1 1 1 = − ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ − − + ⎜ ⎝ ⎛ − = − ⎥ ⎦ ⎤ + ⎟ ⎠ ⎞ +

t a b k a kt b a t k t a m m b k pq pq pq pq pq j pq q p pq 1 1 1 1 1 1 pq b k k k k 1 1 1 − − + pq pq pq pq pq pq b t a t a b t a a kt k k

k − = + − =

− − + 1 1 1 .

Section 4 (Applications of semi-linear credibility theory)

We close this paper by giving the semi-linear hierarchical model used in the appli-cations chapter. Like in Jewell’s hierarchical model we consider a portfolio of contracts, which can be broken up into P sectors each sector consisting of groups of

con-tracts. Instead of estimating: ,

p kp

1 , ,jt+ p

X

(

θp θpj

)

E

[

Xp jt θp θpj

]

μ , = , ,+1 , (the pure net risk premium of the contract

( )

p, j ),

( )

θp E

[

Xp jt θp

]

ν = , ,+1 (the pure net risk

pre-mium of the sector p), we now estimate:

(

, , 1

)

0 Xp jt+

f ,

(

θp θpj

)

E

[

f

(

Xp jt

)

θp θpj

]

μ0 , = 0 , ,+1 , (the pure net risk premium of the contract

( )

p, j ),

( )

θp E

[

f

(

Xp jt

)

θp

]

ν0 = 0 , ,+1 (the pure net risk

premium of the sector p), where p=1,P

(6)

con-sidered: ,

where are functions given in advance. Let us consider the case of one given function in order to approximate

( )

qir p n

p P

q k

i t

r

pqir f X

q

∑∑∑∑

= = = =

+

1 1 1 1

0 α

α

( )

fn

( )

f1 ,...,

1 f

(

, , 1

)

0 Xp jt+

f or ν0

( )

θp and

(

)

j p p θ

θ

μ0 , . We formulate the following theorem:

Theorem 4.1 (Hierarchical semi-linear credibility)

Using the same notations as introduced for the hierarchical model of Jewell and denoting

( )

pjs pjs f X

X0 = 0

and X1pjs = f1

( )

Xpjs

one

ob-tains the following least squares estimates for the pure net risk premiums:

( ) (

)

1

1 0

^

0 θp = mzpm +zpXpzw

ν ,

(

) (

)

1

1 0

^

0 θppj = mzpjm +zpjXpjw

μ (3.1)

where: 1

1 . 1

pjr t

r pj pjr

pjw X

w w

X

=

= ,

1 1 . 1

pjw k

j p pj

pzw X

z z X

p

=

= ,

(

)

[

11 . 11

]

01

.d /c w 1d

w

zpj = pj + pj

(the credibility factor on contract level), with:

(

1

)

' 0 01 Cov Xpjr,Xpjr

d = , d11 =Cov

(

X1pjr,X1pjr'

)

,

'

r

r ≠ , c11=Cov

(

X1pjr,X1pjr

)

=Var

( )

Xpjr1 , and: zp =zp.D01/

[

C11 +

(

zp.−1

)

D11

]

(the credibility factor at sector level), with:

(

1

)

' 0

01 Cov Xpjw,Xpjw

D = ,

(

1

)

' 1

11 Cov Xpjw,Xpjw

D = , jj', C11 =

(

1 1

)

( )

1

, pjw pjw

pjw X Var X

X

Cov =

= .

Remark 4.1: the linear combination of 1 and the random variables X1pjr (p=1,P,

p

k

j =1, , r =1,t) closest to f0

(

Xp,j,t+1

)

and to ν0

( )

θp in the least squares sense equals

( )

θp

ν^0 , and the linear combination of 1 and

the random variables X1pjr (p=1,P,

p

k

j =1, , r =1,t) closest to

(

)

j p p θ

θ

μ0 , in

the least squares sense equals μ

(

θppj

)

.

^ 0

References

[1] Goovaerts, M.J., Kaas, R., Van Herwaarden, A.E., Bauwelinckx,T.:

Insurance Series, volume 3, Efective Actuarial Methods, University of Amster-dam, The Netherlands, 1991.

Referências

Documentos relacionados

A história da humanidade confunde-se com a história da maldade. Afinal, em seu desenvolvimento o ser humano sempre se viu diante da necessidade de fazer escolhas,

Nela, foram apresentados três questionamentos para a análise de aprendizagem significativa: mencionar a relação entre energia e frequência e como ela foi deduzida na

2.1 Verificar a expressão de RANKL em células de órgãos linfoides em modelo de murganhos TEL-JAK2 e em células da linha celular de linfoma EL4.2, por

Tabela 1 – Código de identificação, coordenadas e profundidade (m) do local de colocação dos recetores e marcas de referência utilizados no âmbito do sistema VPS

O planejamento recomendava, ainda, que a qualidade presente nos núcleos educacionais mais avançados chegasse até os núcleos menos avançados. Isso envolveria o

Este estudo privilegia uma análise junto a unidades de produção agrícolas familiares sob a óptica da análise dos sistemas produtivos desenvolvidos nas unidades

VII ENCUENTRO DE ARQUEOLOGÍA DEL SUROESTE PENINSULAR - ESPAÇOS DE NECRÓPOLES DAS PRIMEIRAS SOCIEDADES CAMPONESAS NO CONCELHO DE ARRAIOLOS: UM PONTO DA SITUAÇÃO - LEONOR

A paródia transforma, mas não precisa ridicularizar o seu alvo ou mimetizá-lo, já que nada “existe na paródia que necessite da inclusão de um conceito de ridículo,