• Nenhum resultado encontrado

Fiscal policy in Brazil: from counter-cyclical response to crisis

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Share "Fiscal policy in Brazil: from counter-cyclical response to crisis"

Copied!
48
0
0

Texto

(1)

Novembro de 2015

Working

Paper

407

Fiscal policy in Brazil: from

counter-cyclical response to crisis

(2)

TEXTO PARA DISCUSSÃO 407•NOVEMBRO DE 2015• 1

Os artigos dos Textos para Discussão da Escola de Economia de São Paulo da Fundação Getulio

Vargas são de inteira responsabilidade dos autores e não refletem necessariamente a opinião da

FGV-EESP. É permitida a reprodução total ou parcial dos artigos, desde que creditada a fonte.

Escola de Economia de São Paulo da Fundação Getulio Vargas FGV-EESP

(3)

1

Fiscal policy in Brazil:

from counter-cyclical response to crisis

Márcio Holland

São Paulo School of Economics at Getulio Vargas Foundation, Brazil1

This version: November 10th

, 2015

Abstract

The main goal of this article is to identify the dynamic effects of fiscal policy on output in Brazil

from 1997 to 2014, and, more specifically, to estimate those effects when the output falls below its

potential level. To do so, we estimate VAR (vector autoregressive) models to generate

impulse-response functions and causality/endogeneity tests. Our most remarkable results indicate the

following channel of economic policy in Brazil: to foster output, government spending increases

causing increases in both tax rates and revenue and the short-term interest rate. A fiscal stimulus via

spending seems efficient for economic performance as well as monetary policy; however, the latter

operates pro-cyclically in the way we defined here, while the former is predominantly countercyclical.

As the monetary shock had a negative effect on GDP growth and GDP growth responded positively

to the fiscal shock, it seems that the economic policy has given poise to growth with one hand and

taken it with the other one. The monetary policy is only reacting to the fiscal stimuli. We were not

able to find any statistically significant response of the output to tax changes, but vice versa seems

work in the Brazilian case.

1

Corresponding author: marcio.holland@fgv.br. This working paper was partially written during my mandatory cooling-off period when I spent part of this time as a visiting scholar at Columbia University in the City of New York and for this reason I am very grateful to Professors Albert Fishow, Thomas Trebat, Gray Newman, Sidney Nakahodo, Gustavo

Azenha, and Daniella Diniz, for having me and giving me all support I needed to develop my research. However, all

(4)

2

1. Introduction

The 2008 international financial crisis put fiscal policy at the forefront of debate, particularly

its use in mitigate the painful effects of the crisis on outputs and employment. Probably because of the

lack of widely recognized rules, fiscal policy is generally a controversial issue. The economic

meltdown with its deep and protracted impact on both goods and labor markets presented the perfect

opportunity to approach divergent views about its use. For a few years after the 2008 crash, there was

no room for austerity until government debts skyrocketed. Alas, governments had to shift towards

fiscal retrenchment, even under economic weakness. The results of recent fiscal policy have been

mixed, and its effectiveness remains a disputed issue.

On the other hand, a stream of literature has conducted empirical studies with novel

methodologies in an effort to identify the dynamic and contemporaneous effects of fiscal policy on

outputs. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) estimate a government purchase multiplier for a large

number of OECD countries using a specific form of the STVAR (smooth transition vector

autoregressive) model and have identified a fiscal multiplier in both recession and expansion

circumstances. The model might be considered a refinement of Blanchard and Perotti’s (2002)

specification, who used a simplified structural VAR model. In 2014, Mineshima et al. introduced a

TVAR (threshold vector autoregressive) model to use when regimes are determined by a transition

variable, which is either exogenous or endogenous. More recently, Herwartz and Lütkepohl (2014)

proposed a structural vector autoregression model with Markov switching that combines conventional

and statistical identification of shocks, which can be useful for future studies on fiscal policy.

The main goal of this article is to identify the effect of fiscal shocks on the output in Brazil

from 1997 to 2014, and, more specifically, to estimate those effects when the output falls below its

potential level, as observed during most of the period following the 2008 international meltdown. We

pose an additional question: How low can the output drop when it is already below its potential level

(which we call “negative initial conditions” for the fiscal consolidation program), despite the

composition of the fiscal retrenchment? In other words, after the output has bottomed out, how can

policymakers quickly instill confidence by cutting expenditures and increasing taxes when these

measures were supposed to be implemented an expansionary shock?

To do so, we estimate VAR (vector autoregressive) models to generate impulse-response

functions and causality tests. Our most remarkable results indicate the following channel of economic

policy in Brazil: to foster output, government spending increases, causing increases in both tax rates

and revenue and the short-term interest rate. A fiscal stimulus via spending seems quite efficient for

(5)

3

the former is predominantly countercyclical. We were not able to find any statistically significant

response of the output to tax changes, but we did find a statistically significant response of tax changes

to the output in the Brazilian case.

The contributions of this work are threefold: first, it identifies the response of the output to

fiscal and monetary policy; second, it estimates the impact of recent fiscal measures on the output;

and, third, in line with broader economic literature, it suggests a long-term fiscal plan for Brazil to

spur its effectiveness in reducing output losses.

This work is divided in the following sections. The next section shows Brazil’s recent

experience with fiscal policy and its main results. The third section presents the literature and

discussions of the effectiveness of fiscal policy. The fourth section extrapolates the impulse-response

functions obtained in our research to measure the potential impact of the 2015 fiscal plan on output

and confidence. Ultimately, it is the appropriate moment to present the advantages and caveats of our

empirical procedures. We are most aware of the many drawbacks presented in this sort of time series

analysis. At the end of this section, we suggest a long-term fiscal plan for Brazil using lessons learned

from both Brazil’s recent experience with fiscal policy and our empirical study.

2. The Brazilian Context

Governments across the globe responded to the 2008 crisis with unprecedented expansionary

actions in recent economic history. Monetary and fiscal countercyclical actions were implemented to

both stymie the contamination of the international crisis in financial systems and to resume growth as

soon as possible.

From 2008 to 2010, fiscal and monetary stimuli were overwhelmingly recommended.

However, since 2010, the focus has shifted to fiscal consolidation in advanced economies. Since then,

fiscal results have improved over the world, even though the debt-to-GDP ratios remain high

compared with those before the crisis. More recently, the United States has outperformed the euro

area, where calling for austerity appears to have fallen out of fashion again, as illustrated in the 2015

Greek case.

The fiscal front has deteriorated dramatically in many advanced economies with mixed and far

from outstanding achievements. However, comparing the 1929 Great Depression with the 2008 Great

(6)

4

response, unemployment in the United States peaked at 10 percent in 2010. Though this was still

disturbingly high, it was far below the catastrophic 25 percent scaled in the Great Depression”.

Due to this thought, the Brazilian government took a series of countercyclical policies to

protect the local economy from crumbling. These policies seemed to work well, at least until 2013.

The worst of the crisis was absorbed without any major disruption in the Brazilian economic system.

Most importantly, the economy resumed growth in the 2nd

quarter of 2009; the unemployment rate

did not spike; real wages continued to grow; and consumer and business confidence recovered very

quickly. Nevertheless, after a period of recovery until 2013, the overall growth remained

disappointing, particularly given the very rapid deterioration in 2014, the expected strong contraction

in 2015, and uncertainty about 2016 performance.

From late 2014 to early 2015, Brazil launched a tight fiscal program. The pro-cyclical biased

fiscal consolidation plan is presumably considered the only plausible policy stance when solvency

became the issue rather than economic activity. In Brazil, the diagnosis and prescription have been far

from divergent. However, as highlighted by Frankel (2012), “a pro-cyclical fiscal policy magnifies the

severity of the business cycle”. This controversy motivated this research to assess whether such fiscal

consolidation policies are expected to hurt GDP growth to a greater extend because the economy is

already under contraction. Alternatively, would they spur confidence so that the drag on economic

activity could be avoided?

There is no doubt that fiscal stimuli were needed at that challenging time, when the Brazilian

economy was severely hit by the financial crisis. As for fiscal policy, there were considerable tax

exemptions in 2009. As a result of the actions taken by the government at that time, the country was

able to recover very quickly from the crisis; among other things, Brazil experienced 7.6 percent and

3.9 percent growth in 2010 and 2011, respectively (see table 1).

According to the national account’s new dataset, released on March 27, 2015 by the National

Bureau of Statistics (IBGE), the 2008 crises hit the economy harder and deeper, and the recovery was

faster and better because investment resumed quickly and included a greater share of the GDP

compared with the previous period of the crisis, regardless of its volatility (see figure 1 and 2).

In early 2011, the Federal Administration was able to start applying a fiscal consolidation plan

to cool down the economy. Needless to say, solvency had not been a problem in Brazil for a long

time, as international reserves have been considerable and more than enough to pay for external

liabilities; in addition, the public debt-to-GDP ratio had been decreasing over the years. Thanks to

(7)

5

which could be considered incredibly low in comparison with the debt dynamics in advanced

economies after the crisis. However, the general gross debt-to-GDP ratio is still high in Brazil

compared with that of its peers, although it had been relatively stable, even during most of the period

of countercyclical fiscal policy (see table 1 and figures 2 and 3 for the fiscal results).

Table 1. Brazil: Key Macroeconomic Indicators after the 2008 Crisis (2008-2015)

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015* 2016*

Real GDP Change (%) 5,0 -0,2 7,6 3,9 1,8 2,7 0,1 -3,5 -3,0

Unemployment Rate year average (%) 7,9 8,1 6,7 6,0 5,5 5,4 4,8 6,8 7,5

Investment Change (%), eop 12,7 -1,9 17,8 6,6 -0,6 6,1 -4,4 -12,0 -5,0

CPI Inflation - IPCA (%), eop 5,9 4,3 5,9 6,5 5,8 5,9 6,4 -10,5 -8,5

Benchmark Interest Rate (%), eop 13,75 8,75 10,75 11,0 7,25 10,0 11,75 14,25 14,25

Current Account (% of GDP) -1,7 -1,5 -2,1 -2,0 -2,3 -3,4 -4,4 -4,5 -3,5

FDI (US$ billion) 45,1 25,9 48,5 66,7 65,3 64,0 96,9 60,0 50,0

Foreign Reserves (US$ billion) 207 239 289 352 379 376 374 370 360

Exchange Rate (Real per USD) eop 2,34 1,74 1,67 1,88 2,04 2,35 2,65 4,0 4,5

Primary Result (% of GDP) 3,3 1,9 2,6 2,9 2,2 1,8 -0,6 -2,1 -0,5

Nominal Result (% of GDP) -2,0 -3,2 -2,4 -2,6 -2,3 -3,1 -6,2 -11,1 -9,5

Gross G. Govt Debt (% of GDP) 56,0 59,3 51,8 51,3 54,8 53,3 58,9 69,0 72,0

Net Public Debt (% of GDP) 37,6 40,9 38,0 34,5 32,9 31,5 34,1 33,0 34,0

Notes: Unemployment rate is yearly average of the Monthly Employment Survey (PME); CPI is the broad CPI (IPCA); Benchmark interest rate is the target Central Bank interest rate in the end of period; and exchange rate as in the end of period. eop = end of period. * 2015 and 2016 are author´s forecasts.

Source: Ministry of Finance of Brazil, Central Bank of Brazil, and IBGE.

Even with such policies, the primary surplus targets were fully accomplished, at least until

20122

(see figure 2). However, by mid-2012 to 2013, the recovery appeared to be weaker than

expected, and the Brazilian economic authorities returned to incentives, trying to reignite the

economy3

. In 2013, the economy grew again by 2.7%, and the investment grew 6.1%. A wide tax relief

program and increasing government expenditures, including a broad financial subsidy for credit for

capital goods via public banks, were introduced. The economy reacted reasonably, so the investment

to GDP ratio remained relatively stable at approximately 20.5% until at least 2013, despite its high

variability (see figure 1).

2

Although the one-off revenues had increased in importance after the 2008 crash, responding, for instance, to 0.74% and 0.85% of GDP in 2009 and 2010, respectively, when the full primary surplus delivered was 1.9% and 2.6% of GDP, respectively, or, in 2013, when 0.68% of 1.8% of GDP was one-off revenue. In 2014, one-off revenue was 0.5% of GDP while the primary deficit was 0.6% of GDP. 2015 primary surplus is going to be plenty of on-off revenue, as well.

3

(8)

6

Figure 1. Brazil: Gross Formation of Fixed Capital as % of GDP) 1997-2015

Source: IBGE, updated in November 17, 2015.

Note: Investment as % of GDP measured using current values for GDP and gross formation of fixed capital. 2015 is author´s forecast.

Figure 2: Nominal Fiscal and Primary Results as Share of GDP (%) 1999-2018

Source: Central Bank of Brazil; 2015 - 2018 are author´s forecast.

However, from 2013 to 2014, the output was not responding at all to tax stimuli or even

spending increases. After Brazil graduated to respond to the 2008 crisis using countercyclical fiscal

policies (Vègh and Vulletin, 2013), it experienced a rapid deterioration on the fiscal front in 2014.

Both net and gross public debt increased quickly towards a risky case scenario, so the investment 19,1

18,5

17,0

18,3 18,4 17,9

16,6 17,3 17,1 17,2 18,0

19,4

19,1

20,5 20,6 20,7 20,9

19,7 19,7

17,8

10,0 12,0 14,0 16,0 18,0 20,0 22,0

(5,20)

(3,30) (3,30) (4,40)

(5,20) (2,90)

(3,50) (3,60) (2,70) (2,00)

(3,20) (2,40) (2,50) (2,30) (3,10) (6,20)

(11,10) (9,50)

(7,40) (6,00) 2,80 3,20 3,30 3,20 3,20

3,70 3,70

3,20 3,20 3,30

1,90 2,60 2,90 2,20 1,80

(0,60) (2,10)

(0,50)

0,50 1,00

(12,00) (10,00) (8,00) (6,00) (4,00) (2,00) 2,00 4,00 6,00

1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018

(9)

7

grade rating was no longer assured in the medium term4

. Potential output decreased at the same time

as the output was well below its declining potential output level.

In late 2014 and early 2015, some social benefits were reviewed, and some tax relief was

reverted (tables 5.1 and 5.2 detail these measures). The economy had actually started to adjust itself

during 2014, as the Central Bank had begun a new tightening cycle from April 2013 to July 2014. The

target interest rate increased 375 basis points in an interval of one year. Another 325 basis-point

increase would take place between October 2014 and July 2015. A 700 basis-point monetary shock in

an interval of two years is far from negligible. Its primary side effect was a considerable contraction in

the domestic credit on durable and capital goods, contributing to an additional drop in consumer and

business confidence.

Figure 3: Gross General Debt and Net Public Debt as Share of GDP (%) 2000-2018

Source: Central Bank of Brazil; 2015-2018 are author´s forecasts.

Since mid-2014 the Brazilian economy fell into full disarray: a combination of fiscal crisis with

strong and prolonged GDP contraction in the midst of a political chaos. There are many plausible

explanations for the deceleration of the economic, including the monetary policy shock, associated

curbing in household credit for durable goods, and the gradual increase in some tax rates. Meanwhile,

the economy suffered from a myriad of other events, such as long-standing and severe drought,

corruption scandals involving the largest Brazilian state-run oil company and major entrepreneurs in

4 September 2015, a couple of weeks after the Government had decided to send to Congress the 2016 Budget Law with

deficit, the Standard & Poor´s downgraded the Brazilian sovereign rating to speculative grade.

58,9 61,8

66,7 60,9

56,2 56,1 55,5 56,8 56,0 59,3

51,8 51,3 54,8

53,3 58,9

69,0

72,0 73,4 74,0

46,8 51,5

59,8 54,2

50,2 47,9

46,5 44,6

37,6 40,9

38,0 34,5

32,9

31,5 34,1 33,0 35,0 36,0

38,0

20,0 30,0 40,0 50,0 60,0 70,0 80,0

(10)

8

the civil construction sector, low government popularity amid street protests and general disapproval

regarding the corruption scandals, several bribery schemes, and the 2014 FIFA World Cup. There

are also drivers associated with a profounder phenomenon, as many analysts believe that the previous

consumption-based growth model had already been exhausted. Unfavorable terms of trade are also

remembered as another key driver of such exhaustion.However, I would highlight the exhaustion of

domestic economic cycle as the main guilty for such difficulties, which could dramatize the GDP

performance in coming years. Under this circumstance, the economy became very sensitive to either

domestic or external shocks.

Therefore, fiscal results had been worsening faster than predicted, as the tax revenue had been

frustrated in line with the growth downturn. Gross debt, as a percentage of the GDP, increased from

53.3% in December 2013 to 58.9% in December 2014 and, then, soar to 66%, September 2015. The

gross debt prospects indicate further increases towards over 70% of GDP by the end of 2016 (see

figure 3). In addition, surprisingly, the nominal deficit increased from 3.1 to 6.2% of GDP and

skyrocketed to 9.34% of GDP in September 2015, a movement that was driven by interest payments,

which also increased to 8.9% of GDP. Debt maturity and denomination have deteriorated with the

same intensity.

As risks are tilted towards deep GDP contraction in 2015 and also in 2016, fiscal sustainability

appears to have been an important issue yet again. For instance, in September 2015, the net revenues

of the central government decelerated -4.6% year-to-dates comparing to 2014. In that month, the

government spending also declined -4.0%, in the same terms, although less than the tax frustration.

Consequently, the rolling 12-month primary surplus of the central government decreased to -0.5% of

GDP in September 2015. However, the primary surplus is expected to be delivered will be even

worse and can reach 2.1% of GDP. Tax revenue frustration is only partial explanation. In 2015, the

government could not take into account the relevant amount of one-off revenues; and also it had to

pay the delayed expenses, domestically labeled as “fiscal pedaling”.

Brazil fell into a severe fiscal crisis: the country failures to reach the required primary

surpluses, that is, the level necessary to stabilize debt to GDP, this year and even in coming years.

Therefore, the gross debt to GDP ratio is expected to soar 72% of GDP in 2016, from 53% of GDP,

in 2013. This crisis is predicted to last many years. As far as I can tell, there is no solution, not even a

light at the end of the tunnel.

The causes of such a fiscal situation are closely related to the causes of the GDP contraction.

First, I would consider the stronger-than-expected GDP contraction that leads to tax revenue

(11)

9

related to income transfer programs such as pension benefits5

, LOAS6

, Minha Casa Minha Vida

(housing program), Bolsa-Família (a conditional cash transfer program), etc. I would also include the

reluctance in implementing the appropriate fiscal consolidation plan of early 2015. This hesitancy

amplified the uncertainty on the economic recovery. Finally, because of the second round of the

counter-cyclical fiscal policy implemented in 2012, delayed expenditures had to be settled during

2015. Meanwhile, intense realignment in the regulated price provoked a high short-term inflation. It

seems there are many plausible explanations for such a drama experienced by the Brazilian economy

like a perfect storm.

From a long-term perspective, as seen in figure 4, there has been a considerable change in

government spending since 2003, as it has been focused on reducing income inequality via increasing

conditional cash transfer programs. The federal budget for education and housing has been increasing

over the years. Total federal expenditures increased from 14.6% of GDP in 1997 to 18.6% of GDP at

the end of 2014. Meanwhile, the net total federal tax revenue increased from 15.4% to 19.9% of GDP

in 2010 and then decreased to 18.4% at the end of 2014. The recent fiscal stimuli combined to

increase government expenditures by almost 1% of GDP, while the tax revenue declined from 19.8%

to 18.4% of GDP. However, such recent efforts did not ignite growth in 2014. Many analysts question

whether the overall fiscal multipliers decreased over this period of time. If so, why?

Figure 4. Brazil: Net Tax Revenue and Government Spending (% of GDP)1997-2016

Source: IBGE, and Ministry of Finance, Brazil. 2015 forecast according to the Minister of Planning.

5 The deficit in the general pension system is expected to reach 2.0% of GDP in 2016 from 1.0% of GDP in 2014. 6 LOAS is a welfare public policy for elderly with the benefits indexed to minimum wage. Its expenditure reached 0.7%

of GDP, in 2014.

14,0 15,4

16,0 16,2 17,0

17,7 17,2

18,0

18,6 18,7 18,9 18,8 18,3 20,0

18,7 18,7

19,2

18,4 18,7 18,9

13,7 14,6

14,1 14,4

15,3 15,5 14,9

15,4 16,1

16,6 16,7 16,0

17,2 18,0

16,5

17,1 17,7 18,7

19,0 19,4

12,0 13,0 14,0 15,0 16,0 17,0 18,0 19,0 20,0 21,0

1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 Net Tax Revenue (% GDP)

(12)

10

So, what happened with the government expenditure over time? What are the main

components of such increases? First of all, according to the table 2, the primary spending increased

2.8% of GDP since 2002, which is practically the same growth level of income transfers to

households. Pension benefits show the most relevant increase followed by a welfare benefit for the

elderly called LOAS. Part of the growth is related to both generous eligibility criteria and also public

policy stance, due to the fact that the benefits are indexed to the minimum wage corrections.

As a matter of curiosity, because of this indexation rule, the benefits increased 78%, in real

terms, in the last 10 years. At the same time, the number of beneficiaries increased by 9 million

people, from 23 million to 32 million. Meanwhile, the government decided to enlarge social

programs such as Bolsa Família and Minha Casa Minha Vida. Both are responsible for a 0.63% of

GDP variation in the government consumption during this period of time.

Table 2. The Main Government Expenditure (2002-2014) % of GDP and Percentage Point (pp)

2002

(% GDP)

2010 (% GDP)

2014 (% GDP)

Variation 2002-2014 pp

Variation 2011-2014 pp

PRIMARY SPENDINGS 15,58 16,91 18,35 2,77 1,43

Payroll 4,77 4,28 3,98 -0,79 -0,30

Income Transfer to Households 6,51 8,25 9,31 2,79 1,05

Pension Benefits 5,90 6,56 7,14 1,24 0,58

Unemployment Insurance and Wage Bonus 0,48 0,77 0,98 0,49 0,21

Welfare Benefits (LOAS/RMV) 0,00 0,58 0,70 0,70 0,12

Bolsa-Família (income transfer to poor) 0,13 0,35 0,49 0,36 0,14

Investments 0,82 1,17 1,30 0,48 0,13

Fixed Gross Capital Formation 0,82 1,15 1,04 0,21 -0,11

Minha Casa Minha Vida (housing program) 0,00 0,02 0,27 0,27 0,25

Expenditures 3,48 3,21 3,76 0,28 0,55

Health 1,38 1,34 1,42 0,04 0,07

Education 0,43 0,55 0,76 0,33 0,21

Subsidies* 0,16 0,21 0,16 0,01 -0,04

Others 1,51 1,11 1,41 -0,09 0,31

Net Revenue minus Income Tranfer 11,18 9,87 8,73 -2,46 -1,14

Source: National Treasure and IBGE. Author´s calculation.

Note: * Subsides herein is taking into consideration only those due to the correspondent years. Implicit and explicit subsides, that is, the financial and credit subsides, started to be estimated only in 2012; since then they are 0.9% do GDP in annual average, according to the methodology developed by the Secretariat of Economic Policy at the Minister of Finance.

Moreover, there appears to be an increase of the financial and credit subsides related to the

funding provided by the National Treasure to the state-owned banks. According to the table 2, the

subsidies have been stable over time. However, this measurement doesn´t take into account the

implicit and explicit subsidies, in particular those with delayed payments. Roughly speaking, as part of

(13)

11

enterprises offering low interest rates and the National Treasure was committed to equalize the

interest rates. For instance, the BNDES provided subsidized long-term credit for investments in

machineries and in the infrastructure sector. The difference between the benchmark rate Selic and

the long-term interest rate called TJLP defines the size of the subsidy offered by the BNDES. The

larger the difference between the two rates, the larger the subsidy. According to the calculations

conducted by the Secretariat of Economic Policy, those subsidies reached an annual average of 0.9%

of GDP in 2012-2014, much higher than the data provided in the table 2.

Therefore, more beneficiaries, sizable correction in the benefits and enlarged income transfer

programs could be considered the most relevant factors to explain the augmented expenditures. At

the same time, tax revenues remained relatively stable until 2013. Since 2014 a drop was enough to

make vulnerable the annual fiscal results; yet fiscal expansions were no longer financed by tax

revenue.

The situation became even worse because the deficit in the pension system soared surprisingly

fast. After a certain period of stability, the deficit is projected to double from 2014 to 2016, from 1%

to 2% of GDP. Pension system is responsible for 40% of the total expenditure followed by “payroll”

with 20%. Its expenditures are foreseen to increase more than $25 billion in a very short interval of

time, from 2014 to 2016. Figure 5 shows this risky scenario. As can be fairly seen, the spending has

increased faster than the revenue. The slow increase in the revenue is because of the weakness of the

labor market, which means the higher the unemployment rate, the lower the labor formalization and

then the lower the pension revenues. The spending increase, as mentioned before, is due to the

generous benefit criteria of eligibility, and an upsurge in the minimum wage, which indexes the

benefits.

The demography dynamics in Brazil is also a challenging task for the pension system, since

the population is ageing quickly. This issue is likely to be the major explanation for the growth in the

pension system deficit in the coming years. A comprehensive reform in the system is required. It

would embrace much more strict criteria for newcomers such as minimum eligible age, similar

treatment for gender, de-indexation of benefits from minimum wage, revision of some special

(14)

12

Figure 5. Pension System in Brazil: revenue, spending and deficit (% of GDP) 2005-2016

Source: National Congress.

3. The Literature and Our Case Study

The discussion on the effectiveness of fiscal policy is mostly associated with the fiscal

multiplier, either for government purchases or tax revenue. However, the literature indicates that

there is no unique fiscal multiplier. Furthermore, there is scarce literature about emerging market

economies and no theoretical support for whether multipliers should be expected to be higher or

lower than in the advanced economies (Estevão and Samake, 2013; Ilzetzki et al., 2013; Ilzetzki,

2011; IMF, 2008; and Kraay, 2012). Some studies even conclude that multipliers are negative,

particularly in the longer term (IMF, 2008) and when public debt is high (Ghosh and Rahman, 2008).

One can easily find very divergent fiscal multipliers (see table 2). The multiplier depends on

the critical factors, such as trade openness, the exchange rate regime, the fiscal instrument (whether

spending or tax-based), the debt level, the monetary policy stance (whether normal or

zero-lower-bound), and the state of the economy (whether contracting or expanding). Despite such innumerable

factors, the fiscal multiplier is also sensitive to the method of estimation. For instance, the DSGE

approach has shown larger multiplier than the VAR approach. However, as highlighted by

Mineshima et al. (2014:319), the DSGE model presents difficulties in modeling nonlinearity and does

so differently compared with the Taylor rule for monetary policy, as “there is no widely accepted

fiscal policy (rule) to be included in a DSGE model”.

108 124 140

163 182 212

246

276 307

338 350 366

146 166

185 200 225

255 281

317

357

394

427

491

1,73 1,75

1,65

1,17

1,29

1,10

0,81

0,87

0,97 1,03

1,32

2,00

0,50 1,00 1,50 2,00 2,50

100 200 300 400 500 600

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

(15)

13

Table 2. Fiscal Multipliers Survey: the GDP growth response to fiscal shocks

Authors Country/ Region

Methodology Sample GDP growth response to one SD +/-2S.E innovation on government spending

Blanchard and Perotti (2002)

United States SVAR 1947.1 to 1997.4

Peak values from 0.97 to 1.29 4-quarter response: 0.45 to 0.55 Christiano et al.

(2009)

United States DSGE From 0.8 (no zero bound) to 3.4 (under zero bound)

Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012)

OECD countries

STVAR

1960.1-2010.4

From 0.6 (under expansion) to 2.5 (under recession)

Alesina et al. (2014)

17 OECD countries

Quasi-panel based on a truncated MA representation

1978-2009

From close to 0.0 (if spending-based plan) to -3.0 (if tax-based plan) both after 4-quarter response

Meneshima et al. (2014)

OECD and G7

Countries

TVAR 1970.1 to

2010.4

From 0.72 (positive output gap) to 1.22 (negative output gap) after 4-quarter response

On the other hand, VAR models are subject to several critics. Commodity-exporting

countries, such as Brazil, may experience revenue changes because of booms and busts in the

international commodities market, not because of discretionary fiscal policy. As VAR models suffer

from the omitted variable problem and required quarterly data might not be available for a long

enough time span, they can limit identifying information. In the specific case of the Brazil, the longest

possible time span results in 72 observations over the course of 18 years, including the last years of a

pegged exchange-rate regime (1997-1998). According to Ilzetzki (2011), the more fixed the exchange

rate regime, the larger the fiscal multiplier. Therefore, our results may be biased when we use the full

sample (1997-2014).

Brazil is considered a closed economy, and this attribute is expected to increase the fiscal

multiplier. As Brazilian trade openness does not present relevant changes over time, we do not expect

that any sort of influence of such a key variable on the identification of the multiplier using

country-specific VAR models. Although trade openness is highly recommended for many other reasons, if the

policymakers are really interested in using a discretionary fiscal policy to obtain any real output effect,

the current closed economy makes their fiscal efforts more effective. However, if the effectiveness of

the fiscal policy is falls short of policymakers’ expectations, trade policy should be implemented to

achieve a more economic opening.

Many efforts have been made to show the importance of the fiscal instruments. As widely

(16)

14

and the fiscal multiplier of the former is likely higher than that of the latter. Moreover, the procedure

of Alesina et al. (2014) involves a simulation of a multi-year fiscal plan rather than of individual fiscal

shocks. According to the authors’ findings, “Fiscal adjustments based upon spending cuts are much

less costly, in terms of output losses, than tax-based ones and have especially low output costs when

they consist of permanent rather than stop and go changes in taxes and spending”. As the authors

explain, “The difference between tax-based and spending-based adjustments appears not to be

explained by accompanying policies, including monetary policy. It is mainly due to the different

response of business confidence and private investment”.

Our case study has no multi-year fiscal plan and no fiscal policy adjustment based only on

spending cuts. The only goal is to reach the annual announced primary surplus, regardless of the

instrument and composition. Late 2014, 1.2% of GDP expressed in terms of the amount of money

(e.g., $22 billion) is due as public sector consolidated primary surplus by end of 2015, and there was

also a target of 2.0% of GDP for the coming years. It was hard to identify the proportion of spending

cuts and tax hikes needed to obtain such surpluses. However, the fiscal measures announced (see

table 5.1 and 5.2) defined approximately 2.2% of GDP7

in overall savings through spending cuts

(approximately 1.75% of GDP) and increased taxes (approximately 0.54% of GDP).

Alas, these measures did not directly assure a movement from a deficit of 0.6% of GDP, in

December 2014, to a surplus of 1.2% of GDP in December 2015. Actually, another primary deficit is

expected in 2015 and, moreover, surplus for next year is not guaranteed. The government most likely

will deliver a deficit of at least 1.1% of GDP, instead of a surplus of 1.2% of GDP announced last

December 2014. It is a dramatically poorer scenario. But, why such an unpleasant surprise? First,

most of the savings come from the 2015 federal budget cut, which is generally overestimated; second,

the increase in tax rates does not imply the same increase in tax revenue, which is more related to

economic performance8

; and, finally, the revision in some social benefits takes time to contribute to

fiscal efforts. Moreover, alongside the extreme deterioration of the domestic economic activity

pushing down the tax revenue, payments of delayed expenditures have worsened the fiscal balance.

Austerity brings more contraction, and such a circumstance is tough to obtain tax revenue. The back

and forth economic policy stance during the year also played its role for such drama. It had to include

low extraordinary revenue that put a negative bias to the fiscal balance.

7 This value is overestimated as it includes cut in an inflated budget. Taking into account only the structural spending

cuts, the plan would retrench only 0.26% of GDP.

8

(17)

15

Our case study is more associated with shifts in fiscal policy over time than with long-term

fiscal consolidation programs. The VAR model can capture this short-term dynamic adjustment,

although Brazil instead have a fiscal plan that is well designed and communicated for the coming

years. In line with Alesina et al. (2014), this sort of plan could result in a shorter recession than would

be expected in our case study, as experienced recently.

The debt level is very important, especially with the debt threshold is below the international

threshold, as in the Brazilian case. According to the economic literature, the lower the debt threshold,

the smaller the fiscal multiplier. In Ilzetzki (2011), the fiscal multiplier can eventually become negative

when the debt exceeds its threshold. Brazil obtained sound results in terms of net debt levels until at

least 2013; the gross debt-to-GDP ratio is higher than those of its peers, and debt maturity has

remained a concern. The implicit interest rate of the debt is much higher than the monetary policy

rate, which is considered one of the most persistently highest in the world. Because of this debt

constraint, Brazil is expected to show a small fiscal multiplier. In other words, fiscal stimuli are

welcome during contractions, without losing sight of debt sustainability in the medium term.

The state of the economy is one critical factor of the fiscal multiplier. Using regime-switching

models, Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) estimated the effects of fiscal policies that might vary

over the business cycle. They found considerable differences in the size of spending multipliers

during recessions and expansions, with fiscal policy being considerably more effective in recessions

than in expansions. As can be seen in the figure 6, Brazil’s output is running well below its potential

level, as roughly measured by the HP filter, throughout 2014, and it will most likely be the same

throughout 2015 and 2016. In this scenario, the fiscal multiplier is expected to be larger than the

previous years. Puzzlingly, fiscal stimuli recently seem to not being working well at all.

As is well known, the effectiveness of fiscal policy is heterogeneous under normal

circumstances (Favero, Giavazzi, and Perego, 2011). In the case of conventional monetary policy,

fiscal laxity may have a restricted impact on output. Otherwise, countercyclical fiscal policy is likely to

smooth the business cycle. The debt level is a constraint in both cases but is most likely a major issue

for developing economies. In line with the Easterly’s (2013) idea, part of the public debt increase is

considered “normal” in advanced economies. However, in the aftermath of the 2008 turmoil,

conventional monetary policy has been used mostly in developing economies, where debt intolerance

(Reinhart et al., 2003) is still considered a relevant phenomenon.

A simplified debt sustainability assessment unveils such a relevant constraint for the coming

years and the peril of a downgrade in the sovereign rating. Under a baseline scenario, gross general

(18)

16

to stabilize debt are higher than that formerly targets announced by Brazilian policymakers for 2015

and 2016; however, it is quite difficult to reach even that 1.2% of GDP target for 2015 and the 2% of

GDP target for 2016. A bleak slowdown does not allow tax revenue to increase, even with the tax

benefit withdrawals announced9

early 2015.

In sum, an upward bias for the fiscal multiplier is expected, which is associated with a couple

of years under the pegged exchange-rate regime (1997-1998) and with the contractions during the

2008 financial turmoil and since at least the middle of 2013. There has been a downward bias for the

fiscal multiplier caused by the debt level and the accompanying conventional monetary policy stance.

There is also the recessionary bias of the recently announced fiscal measures (in late 2014 and early

2015).

Figure 6. Brazil Output Gap - % Quarterly Data (1997-2014)

Note: Output gap is measured as the difference between the actual output in log and the estimate output in log according to the HP filter (Lampda = 1,600).

3. The Empirical Model and Findings

We roughly estimate the basic VAR model. The specification considers aggregate government

purchases in the linear model with no regime shifts or control for expectations, including the

following ordering [G T Y i] for Cholesky decomposition:

(1) = � �, � �−1+

where ≡ [ , �, is a three-dimensional vector in the logarithms of quarterly taxes, spending,

benchmark interest rate, and GDP, all in real terms. ≡ [�, �, �]′ is the corresponding vector of

reduced-form residuals, which generally have nonzero cross correlations.

9

(19)

17

We then expand our estimations to take into account confidence indicators and disaggregate

variables. In ≡ [ , �, ], Xt is an n-dimensional vector, including business and consumer

confidence, private investment and household consumption10

, besides interest rate and real GDP.

We are aware that VAR models have been subject to several criticisms (IMF, 2010; Romer,

2011; and Caldara and Kamps, 2012). DSGE models are alternative approaches, but they also have

drawbacks. We are also aware that other key macroeconomic variables could be taken into

consideration, such as trade openness, debt level, and financial market deepening. However, the

changes over time used in our estimations are negligible. We would highly recommend including

them in case of a panel-based empirical analysis, as those variables most likely change across

countries.

We adopted the VAR Granger causality/block exogeneity Wald tests to examine the causal

relationships among the variables. Under this system, an endogenous variable can be treated as

exogenous. We used the chi-square (Wald) statistics to test the joint significance of each of the other

lagged endogenous variables in each equation of the model and also for the joint significance of all

other lagged endogenous variables in each equation of the model. The chi-square test statistics for

some variables (X, for example) represent the hypothesis that the lagged coefficients of that variable in

the regression equation of another variable (Y, for example) are equal to or different from zero. If

equal to zero, that variable (X) is Granger causal for Y at some level of significance, which suggests

that Y is not influenced by X. The null hypothesis of block exogeneity is then rejected for all

equations in the model.

The first group of empirical results is related to a very simplified VAR model and its pairwise

Granger causality and block exogeneity Wald tests. Information criteria from Akaike, Hannan-Quinn

and Schwarz were used to select the most parsimonious, correct model. Most tables and figures

presenting the results appear in the Annex. We have conveniently separated some figures to show

alongside the text.

We estimated two different VAR models as follows:

(1) VAR 2: [Y, S, T, i]

10 These results are not reported herein, as they did not add any relevant analysis, but the results are available upon

(20)

18

where Y is the GDP; S is the government expenditure as a percentage of GDP deflated by IPCA; T is

the net tax revenue as a percentage of GDP deflated by IPCA; and

i

is the Selic interest rate in annual

percentage terms.

(2) VAR 1: [h, FI, i]

where h is the output gap measure, i.e., the difference between the actual GDP and the potential

GDP according to the HP filter; FI is the fiscal impulse measure, i.e., the variation of the primary

surpluses as a share of GDP; and

i

is the variation of Selic interest rate in annual percentage terms.

The VAR model in specification (2) allows us to simultaneously identify the direction of fiscal

and monetary policy. As we split up the sample to cope with the 2008 crash, it is also possible to

observe the eventual shift in the economic policy stance before and after the crisis.

Then, this second specification is more related to the policy stance, whether countercyclical or

pro-cyclical. For instance, fiscal policy could be labeled as countercyclical or pro-cyclical when the

sign of the fiscal impulse is equal to or different from (expansionary or contractionary, respectively)

the signal of the deviation of the real output from its tendency level (the output gap). Figure 7

illustrates this idea. According to this figure, one can have, for example, countercyclical policy under

fiscal adjustments and pro-cyclical stances during output expansion. It is always a matter of the

direction of the fiscal policy alongside the business cycle.

Figure 7. Fiscal Expansion and Contraction

GDP Output

Fiscal

Impulse

Output Gap (-) Output Gap (+)

Expansion (-) Countercyclical Pro-cyclical

Contraction (+) Pro-cyclical Countercyclical

There have been many discussions about countercyclical versus pro-cyclical fiscal policies and

when and how much uses each type. However, the first challenge involves assessing how much of

effort the policymakers intend to make. The most accurate way to infer this effort is by assessing

structural fiscal results instead of conventional ones11

. Before moving on, it is important to consider

that the structural fiscal results are still behind the times when the topic is fiscal rules, mainly because

they are well known only quarters or even years after the fiscal practice is implemented, as they

11

(21)

19

depend on many complex calculations. However, if the purpose is to define the intensity of the fiscal

policy, they are more appropriate, even though the other methods are not necessarily incorrect.

The structural fiscal results can be briefly defined as results that are consistent with the

potential output, under the condition of equilibrium in the asset and commodity prices and free of

one-off revenues. It may be considered an accurate form to express the fiscal discretionary effect on

the aggregate demand. As fiscal results can be influenced by many factors beyond the control of

economic authorities, structurally based results consider only the effective fiscal efforts of

policymakers. Conventional results, such as primary surpluses, are not capable of measuring such

efforts because they depend on others factors, such as the business cycle, and, in turn, changes in

asset and commodity prices, changes in output composition, and one-off revenues.

Figure 8 illustrates the use of one-off revenues in Brazil, which increased dramatically after the

2008 crisis. One-off revenues includes: concessions revenue in most years, judicial deposit (in 2009),

Eletrobras’ dividend (in 2009 and 2010), Petrobras capitalization (most of 2010 one-off revenue),

Sovereign Fund of Brazil (created in 2008 and used in 2012), tax refining program (in 2009, 2011,

2013, and 2014), other one-off revenues, dividends in advance, and FND subsidize. The annual

average of one-off revenue from 2009 to 2014 (after the crisis) was 0.6% of GDP when the average of

the annual primary surpluses was 1.8% of GDP, representing, then, 1/3 of the annual fiscal results.

How much policymakers intend to pledge or cut in terms of stimulus or retrenchment,

respectively, during a certain period of time, depends on the fiscal impulse, that is, the difference

between the current structural fiscal result and the previous result. Fiscal policy could be labeled as

countercyclical or pro-cyclical when the signal of the fiscal impulse is equal to or different from

(expansionary or contractionary, respectively) the signal of the deviation of the real output from its

tendency level (the output gap).

Figure 8: One-Off Revenue, 2002-2014 (US$ Billion and % of GDP)

Source: Secretariat of Economic Policy, Minister of Finance of Brazil. Notes: We use 3.0 Brazilian Real per one US Dollar.

-4000,0 -2000,0 0,0 2000,0 4000,0 6000,0 8000,0 10000,0 12000,0 14000,0

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

0,74

0,02 0,06 0,04 0,04 0,08

-0,23 0,74

0,85

0,38 0,53

0,68 0,50

-0,20 0,00 0,20 0,40 0,60 0,80 1,00

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

(22)

20

Here, the idea is different for the case of monetary policy. It could be pro-cyclical or

countercyclical when the signal of the monetary policy shock (changes in the interest rate) is equal to

or different from (contractionary or expansionary, respectively) the output gap. Then, for instance, we

label arbitrarily a pro-cyclical monetary policy when the interest rate increases during an expansion.

Otherwise, it would be a countercyclical orientation.

We also conducted a multivariate pairwise Granger causality test/block exogeneity Wald test

derived from the VAR model to examine additional causal relationships between the key variables in

the model. This test estimates the χ square value of the coefficients of lagged endogenous variables.

The null hypothesis in this test is that the lagged endogenous variables do not Granger cause the

dependent variable.

Data Descriptions

The models are estimated over three samples: first, the full sample spanning from 1997 to

2014 and then two other samples to determine the eventual effect of the 2008 crash: one from 1997

to 2007 and one from 2008 to 2014. We are aware that the small size of the sample of times series

diminishes the degrees of freedom and the robustness of the estimates.

Table 3 shows data descriptions and the sources used here. All series, if necessary, are

deflated with the Broad Consumer Price Index (IPCA) and divided by GDP.

According to our sample, the GDP has grown an average of 0.73% in quarter-over-quarter

terms, which is approximately 3.0% in annualized terms; investment has grown a little faster at 3.2%;

and consumption is coupled with the GDP growth (table 4). There are different speeds over time

because investment has grown faster and consumption has resumed faster than the GDP after the

2008 turmoil. The average investment as share of GDP is 18.7%, with some increases after the crisis

coming to approximately 20%, which could introduce an intriguing question. Net tax revenue as share

of GDP has been higher than the government spending-to-GDP ratio. The volatility of the investment

rates, as measured by standard deviation (approximately 14% in annualized terms), is quite

(23)

21

Table 3. Data descriptions and sources

Variable Source

Real GDP IBGE

General Government Primary Surplus Ministry of Finance

Net Federal Tax Revenue (total government revenue minus

net transfers)

Ministry of Finance

General Government Consumption Ministry of Finance

Business Confidence Indicator CNI, FGV, and Fecomercio

Household Confidence Indicator CNI, FGV, and Fecomercio

Private Investment (Fixed Capital Gross Formation) IBGE

Household Consumption IBGE

Broad Consumer Price Index (IPCA) IBGE

Benchmark Nominal Interest Rate (Selic) Central Bank of Brazil

Table 4. Basic Statistics for 1997-2014 (N=72, QoQ Change)

GDP Growth

(%)

Investment Growth

(%)

Consumption Growth

(%)

Investment (%GDP)

Tax Revenue (%GDP)

Governement Spending

(%GDP)

Minimum -4.09 -10.0 -3.0 18.4 13.4 13.7

Maximum 2.76 8.5 2.98 21.6 24.7 20.9

Mean 0.73 0.79 0,72 18.7 17.7 16.03

Standard Deviation

1.17 3.3 1,14 1.45 1.8 1.47

Empirical Findings

Our models were generally run with four lags, according to the information criteria12

. We

estimate a model for the full sample (1997-2014) and for the period before (1997-2007) and after

(2008-2014) the crash13

. We first present results of the impulse-response functions and then the VAR

Granger causality tests/block exogeneity Wald tests, from the VAR 1 specification and then from the

VAR 2 specification. The figures and tables presenting these results appear in the Annex.

First, generally speaking, it is remarkable that the fiscal stimulus via government spending has

a positive and statistically significant impact on GDP growth and that the monetary policy has a

12

The following information criteria are used here: LR = sequential modified LR test statistic (each test at the 5% level); FPE = final prediction error, AIC = Akaike information criterion; SC = Schwarz information criterion; and HQ = Hannan-Quinn information criterion.

13

(24)

22

negative and statistically significant impact on GDP growth, regardless of the model and specification.

It is also worth mentioning the channels through which these findings work in the model. On the one

hand, unexpected shocks in government expenditures generally spark growth; on the other hand, they

lead to positive shocks in the short-term interest rate that hinder growth. Additionally, there is no

statistically significant response from any other key macroeconomic variable, including GDP growth

and the confidence related to unexpected shocks in net tax revenue. However, tax revenue responded

slightly positively to shocks in government expenditures and growth. There are mixed results

associated with the relationship among our other key variables, such as government expenditures, net

tax revenues, the fiscal impulse and the short-term interest rate.

More specifically, we first examine the impact of the unexpected structural shock of taxes on

other key variables. According to the VAR Granger causality/block exogeneity Wald test, we cannot

reject the null hypothesis that net tax revenue does not Granger cause GDP growth, but we can reject

the hypothesis that it does not cause government expenditures. GDP growth Granger causes tax

revenue only when we use the full sample and with less statistical significance when we use the

bub-samples from after/before the crash.

According to the impulse-response functions, the response of GDP growth to unexpected

shocks in tax revenue is small and not statistically significant; the size of the response and its

significance is reasonable only when we take the short-term interest rate out of the VAR specification.

In line with the Granger causality test, the response of government spending to a tax shock is positive

and statistically significant.

Therefore, we can summarize the role played by tax policy as follows: increased government

spending increases tax revenue, and the greater the GDP growth, the greater the tax revenue. It seems

that tax revenue has increased because the government has chosen to stimulate the economy using its

spending power.

Now, we turn to the effect of the structural shock of government expenditures. According to

the Granger causality test, one can reject the hypothesis that government spending does not Granger

cause GDP growth, regardless of the sample and the specification.

On the other hand, government spending Granger causes the benchmark interest rate.

Therefore, fiscal policy seems to be very efficient in reviving growth in Brazil, even though it comes

(25)

23

In terms of dynamic effects, the GDP growth responds positively, although not necessarily

different from zero, to unexpected shocks in government expenditures, reaching its peak after four

quarters; its peak changes with the sample; using the full sample, the peak is 0.5, but the peak doubles

to 1.1 in the period after the 2008 crash; it is approximating 0.4 for the sample before the crash. It

seems that fiscal policy is even more effective during difficult times. In sum, the size of such impact,

which is generally associated with the fiscal multiplier, is approximately 0.5 after 4 quarters for normal

times and approximately 1.1 after four quarters in difficult times, including the aftermath of the 2008

financial crisis14

.

Meanwhile, GDP growth responds negatively and statistically significantly to the unexpected

shock in the benchmark interest rate. Surprisingly, the response is close to 1.1 for the sample after the

crisis and 0.5 for the full sample and the sample before the crisis. There is no difference between the

monetary and fiscal shocks in terms of the dynamics over time because both affect the GDP after four

quarters.

As the monetary shock had a negative effect on GDP growth and GDP growth responded

positively to the fiscal shock, it seems that the economic policy “has given poise to growth with one

hand and taken it with the other one”.

For instance, some authors have conducted studies on the impact of the rock-bottom interest

rate policy in the US. According to a general New Keynesian model, as explored in Christiano,

Eichenbaum and Rebelo (2010), the government spending fiscal multiplier can be larger than usual

thanks to the monetary policy stance. They analyzed a special case of the zero-lower-bound interest

rate policy in the US and concluded that this policy amplifies the impact of expansionary stimuli.

According to these authors, “First, when the central bank follows a Taylor rule, the value of

the government-spending multiplier is generally less than one. Second, the multiplier is much larger if

the nominal interest rate does not respond to the rise in government spending. For example, suppose

that government spending goes up for 12 quarters and the nominal interest rate remains constant. In

this case the impact multiplier is roughly 1.6 and has a peak value of about 2.3. Third, the value of the

multiplier depends critically on how much government spending occurs in the period during which

the nominal interest rate is constant…for government spending to be a powerful weapon in combating

output losses associated with the zero-bound state” (p. 5-6).

14We, herein, are not intentionally using such coefficients as the well-known fiscal multiplier because of drawbacks in the

(26)

24

Does the monetary policy amplify the fiscal policy in the Brazil case? The answer is “no”. The

monetary policy rate has been diminishing over time but has been reacting to the fiscal policy. It is a

sort of “give-and-take policy”, as the persistently high short-term interest rate (see figure 9) under a

conventional Taylor rule-based action considerably reduces the government spending fiscal

multiplier. We also use the actual US federal funds rate to run a VAR that hypothetically assumes a

zero-lower-bound monetary policy in Brazil. In such a hypothetical situation, the response of GDP

growth to unexpected shocks in government expenditures would almost double, from 0.5 to 1.0 using

the full sample and from 1.1 to 1.8 using sample after the 2008 crash, both under the dramatic

assumption of a zero-lower-bound interest rate in Brazil. Figure 9 shows this story. For instance, the

short-term interest rate increased from 2009 to 2012, and, after a lax cycle, another tight policy stance

arose in 2013. While fiscal policy was predominantly operating in a countercyclical direction,

monetary policy was operating in a pro-cyclical direction.

Figure 9: Benchmark Nominal Interest Rate (2008-2015), annual %

Source: Central Bank of Brazil

Now, we use the VAR 2 [h, F, i] specification to analyze the direction, i.e., countercyclical or

pro-cyclical, of economic policy. The VAR was run with four lags following the information criteria.

At first glance, as seen in figure 11, fiscal policy has been predominantly countercyclical, and

monetary policy has been predominantly pro-cyclical15

. An unexpected shock in the fiscal impulse

(the change in the primary surplus-to-GDP ratio) has a positive and statistically significant impact on

the output gap (the difference between the actual GDP and its potential level). One can clearly see

that the government increases its fiscal results when the economy is doing better and reduces them

under contractions. According to the impulse-response function, the fiscal impulse responds

positively and statistically significantly to the unexpected shock of GDP growth, and vice versa,

15Again, we arbitrarily labeled “pro-cyclical” monetary policy when the interest rate follows the business cycle in the

same direction. This case could fairly be denominated as a counter-cyclical fiscal policy.

(27)

25

reaching a peak of 1.2 after three quarters and remaining relatively stable afterwards. Using the

sub-sample after the 2008 crash, this peak jumps up to 1.9, which clearly shows the important role played

by fiscal stimuli during hard times.

Figure 10. Impulse-Response Function VAR [Y, S, T, i]

Meanwhile, unexpected shocks in monetary policy have a negative and statistically significant

impact on the output gap. Monetary policy in Brazil seems more effective than expected. In a

dynamic analysis, the output gap slump in response to the unexpected monetary shock, bottoming out

at -0.5 after two quarters, then increases to -1.7 after five quarter, remaining relatively stable

afterwards. During tough times, using the sub-sample from 2008 to 2014, this peak elevates to 2.0.

The main lesson that we can take from these empirical findings is that monetary shocks have been

large enough to counterweigh any fiscal stimulus over time.

It is worth mentioning that monetary policy has reacted to fiscal policy because the benchmark

interest rate responds negatively to unexpected shocks in the primary surplus. We were not able to

accept the responses of the interest rate set by the Central Bank to shocks nor to net tax revenue nor

to government spending, but we can now observe the importance of primary surpluses to the Central

(28)

26

increase in the primary surplus as share of GDP triggers a 30 basis-point decreases in the short-term

interest rate after two quarters.

Figure 11. Impulse-Response Function VAR [h, F, i]

We also include indicators of confidence in variations of both of our VAR specifications16

. As

there would be a causal relationship running from the indicators of business and consumer

confidences to output and investment, we inquired about whether confidence might be resumed

before investment and output. According to Alesina et al. (2014), “the confidence of investors also

does not decrease much after an expenditure-based adjustment and promptly recovers and increases

above the baseline; it instead falls for several years after a tax-based adjustment”.

As leading indicators, indicators of business and consumer confidences could be able to

foresee prospects of output and investment for the coming years. However, the results when we run

specifications that include such variables do not change our previous findings. Confidence indicators,

both for businesses and consumers, respond less than GDP growth to shocks in government

expenditures, net tax revenues, and fiscal impulses. It seems that when the scenario for growth comes

to entrepreneurs’and consumers’ minds, the economy has already found a path to growth.

16

Imagem

Table 1. Brazil: Key Macroeconomic Indicators after the 2008 Crisis (2008-2015)
Figure 2: Nominal Fiscal and Primary Results as Share of GDP (%) 1999-2018
Figure 3: Gross General Debt and Net Public Debt as Share of GDP (%) 2000-2018
Figure 4. Brazil: Net Tax Revenue and Government Spending (% of GDP)1997-2016
+7

Referências

Documentos relacionados

Long term interest rates respond to changes in expected future short term rates; if the period of low interest rates was interpreted as evidence of a change in the response of

Outro recurso utilizado como ferramenta de participação social são os consórcios de saúde, que por meio da instituição do Sistema Único de Saúdeganharam

artificialmente a fase de supervisão – fase em que, segundo a Autora, o nemo tenetur não será invocável, uma vez em que ainda não existe processo algum – com o

Assim como também, compreender que a primeira metade do século XX foi muito importante para o desenvolvimento e conceção do espaço da cozinha, devido à participação de

Por outro lado, credores quirografários (sem garantias) podem preferir a manutenção da empresa por meio de uma reestruturação, na es- perança de receber algo caso ela venha a se

Our main argument is that the 2014-2017 fiscal crisis is explained partly be- cause of the colossal budget rigidity that originates from the latest Brazilian Fed- eral

Implicações para as políticas sociais das utopias desenvolvimentistas sob a égide do credo neoliberal: o caso particular da Seguridade Social

In macroeconomics theory, fiscal policy itself involves government actions to adjust government expenditure levels (G), tax rates (T), and sovereign debt (D) to intervene