• Nenhum resultado encontrado

Testing production functions used in empirical growth studies

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Share "Testing production functions used in empirical growth studies"

Copied!
12
0
0

Texto

(1)

Nº 507

ISSN 0104-8910

Testing production functions used in empirical growth studies

Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira

João Victor Issler

(2)

Testing Production Functions Used in Empirical Growth Studies

Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira

João Victor Issler

Samuel de Abreu Pessôa

Graduate School of Economics - EPGE

Getulio Vargas Foundation

March 2003

Abstract

We estimate and test two alternative functional forms, which have been used in the growth literature, representing the aggregate production function for a panel of countries: the model of Mankiw, Romer and Weil (Quar ter ly Jour nal of Economi cs, 1992), and a mincerian formulation of schooling-returns to skills. Estimation is performed using instrumental-variable techniques, and both functional forms are confronted using a Box-Cox test, since human capital inputs enter in levels in the mincerian speciÞcation and in logs in the extended neoclassical growth model.

1

Introduction

In this paper we estimate and test two alternative functional forms, that have been used in the growth literature, representing the aggregate production function for a panel of countries. The Þrst model has a long tradition in this literature and was proposed by Mankiw Romer and Weil (1992), among others. The second is a mincerian formulation of schooling-returns to skills, traditionally used in the labor-economics literature, e.g., Mincer (1974), but recently incorporated into the growth literature as well; see Klenow, Rodriguez-Clare (1997), Hall and Jones (1999), and Bils and Klenow (2000)1. Islam(1995) recognizes that

human capital is important in the growth process, but claims that the unresolved question is: “in what exact way”? Since the basic difference between these two competing models is the way in which human capital affects output — in the mincerian model human capital enters the production function exponentially

We gratefully acknowledge the comments and suggestions of an anonymous referee, Costas Azariadis, Gary Hansen, Marcos

B. Lisboa, Carlos Martins-Filho, Naércio Menezes, Alberto Trejos, Farshid Vahid, Martin Uribe, and several seminar participants around the world. All remaining errors are ours. Rafael Martins de Souza provided excellent research assistance. The authors also acknowledge theÞnancial support of CNPq-Brazil and PRONEX.

Corresponding author. Praia de Botafogo 190, 1125, Rio de Janeiro, RJ, 22253-900, Brazil. Email addresses of the authors

are, respectively, ferreira@fgv.br, jissler@fgv.br, pessoa@fgv.br

1Strictly speaking, both models are “neoclassical,” in the sense that both have marginal diminishing returns to input

(3)

while in the Mankiw, Romer and Weil model it enters the production function in levels — we propose here to distinguish between them by means of an econometric test based on the Box and Cox(1962) transformation. Contrary to the bulk of the previous empirical growth literature, we estimate directly the logarithmic version of the production function, which makes performing a Box-Cox test a direct exercise. Panel-data estimation is performed using instrumental-variable techniques, after a careful search for appropriate instru-ments. Also, a variety of speciÞcation tests are performed to validate the Þnal choice of model. The data used in our study are extracted from Summers and Heston (1991, mark 5.6) and Barro and Lee (1996), and includes 95 countries in different stages of economic development, with observations ranging from 1960 to 1985.

2

Model Speci

Þ

cation

The Mankiw, Romer and Weil model (MRW),2 has the following speciÞcation when constant returns of scale

are not imposed:

Yit= AitKitαH

φ

it(Litexp (g·t))β, (1)

where Yit,Kit,Hit,Lit, andAitare respectively output, physical capital, human capital, raw labor inputs,

and productivity for country i in period t, where i = 1,· · ·, N, and t = 1,· · ·, T and g is the exogenous technological progress, which is the same across countries. In per-worker terms, the equation above reduces to:

lnyit= lnAi+ αlnkit+ φlnhit+ (α+ β+ φ−1) lnLit+ βg·t+ ηit, (2)

where lower-case variables are in per-worker terms, andAitis decomposed into a time-invariant component Ai and an error component that varies acrossiandt,ηit.

In the mincerian speciÞcation (Mincer (1974)) there is only one type of labor in the economy, which has skill-level determined by educational attainment. It is assumed that the skill-level of a worker withhyears of schooling isexp (φh)greater than that of a worker with no education at all, leading to the following function:

Yit= AitKitα(exp (φhit)Litexp (g·t))β. (3)

In per-worker terms, the equation above reduces to:

lnyit= lnAi+ αlnkit+ βφhit+ (α+ β−1) lnLit+ βg·t+ ηit. (4)

Econometrically, the basic difference between equations (2) and (4) is whether human capital enters the (logarithmic version of the) production function in levels or in logs. We therefore estimate a general regression model:

lnyit= lnAi+ λ1lnkit+ λ2

µ

it−1

θ

+ λ3·t+ λ4lnLit+ ηit, (5)

(4)

3

Econometric Estimation, Testing, and Results

Consider the Box and Cox (1962) transformation for a given regressor:

it−1

θ . (6)

Since lim θ→0

xθit−1

θ = ln (xit), and lim

θ→1

xθit−1

θ = xit−1, for the logarithmic transformation to be valid we must

have θ = 0, and for the series xit to enter the regression in levels we must have θ = 1. The hypotheses

that human capital enters the production function in levels or in logs can thus be tested using a Box-Cox transformation for the human-capital stock by means of a Wald test, with H0 : θ = 1and H0 : θ = 0

respectively.

In estimating either (2) or (4) we must take into account thatlnkit,lnhit, and hitare correlated with

ηit, which requires using instrumental-variable techniques. We propose using the following instruments for lnkit,lnhit, andhit, respectively:

1

Ni

X

j∈{Ni}

lnkjt−1, (7)

1

Ni

X

j∈{Ni}

lnhjt−1, (8)

1

Ni

X

j∈{Ni}

hjt−1, (9)

where Ni represents the number of additional countries in the same continent that country i is in, and

©

Niª represents the set of countries in that continent that are not countryi, i.e., (7), (8), and (9) represent,

respectively, rest-of-the-continent average lagged (log of the) capital stock, (log of the) human capital stock, and level of the human capital stock. Hence, instruments are country speciÞc.

Rest-of-continent instruments such as (7), (8), and (9) are promising, since one could expecta priori that countries in the same continent are similar in several dimensions and are relatively more integrated, making instruments correlated with regressors. The fact that countryiis excluded from computing rest-of-continent averages makes the latter more likely to be uncorrelated with country’s i error: ηit, which can be formally tested for over-identiÞed models; a basic references is Sargan (1958).

With appropriate instruments we estimate (5)3. We assume that the variance of η

it does not change

across t, although it is allowed to change across i. Due to this structure, our estimation method weights data in each equation by the reciprocals of the standard deviation of country-speciÞc errors, similar to the procedure in weighted two-stage least squares. The only difference here to weighted two-stage least squares is that we use equation-speciÞc instruments and not the whole set of instruments. The constant term in each regression equation uses country-speciÞc dummies, similar to Þxed-effect estimation in a completely linear setup.

Based on the results of Wald tests with H0 :θ = 1and H0 :θ = 0, we could either choose one of the

models (2) or (4), or reject (not reject) both. If one is chosen we then perform estimation of the chosen 3In (5) we also need instruments forlnL

(5)

one using the same procedure described above: weighted instrumental-variable technique. Orthogonality tests between errors and instruments using the procedure in Sargan(1958) is performed. Since we have country-speciÞc instruments we perform Sargan tests equation-by-equation.

The panel data set used ranges from 1960 to 1985, and combines macroeconomic data for 95 countries in the mark 5.6 of the Summers and Heston (SH, from now on) data set with human-capital measures extracted from Barro and Lee (1996). We decided to interpolate human-capital measures toÞt annual frequency.4 The

time span was restricted from 1960 to 1985. The speciÞc series used are the following: yit is the ratio of

real GDP (at 1985 international prices) and the number of workers in the labor force, extracted from SH;

kit is the physical capital series per worker. The physical capital series is constructed using real investment

data from SH (at 1985 international prices) and the Perpetual Inventory Method;5 h

it is Barro and Lee’s

(1996) series of average years of completed education of the labor force, interpolated (in levels) toÞt annual frequency.

3.1

Model Estimation Results

Estimates of parameters in (5) are presented in Table 1 below.

<include Table 1 here>

First, the estimate of θ is 0.86, closer to unity, favoring the mincerian speciÞcation for the production function. Indeed, Wald test results forθ= 1andθ= 0did not reject the mincerian model, although strongly rejected the MRW model. Hence ourÞnal conclusion is in favor of the mincerian model against the MRW model. This is a relevant result, since a group of authors in the growth literature have recently made the case for the use of the mincerian form of the production function; see Hall and Jones (1999), Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare (1997) and Bils and Klenow (1999), among others. Because their argument is entirely based on microeconomic evidence — e.g., Psacharopoulos (1994) — the evidence presented here using the Box-Cox transformation conÞrms the appropriateness of their approach from a formal econometric point of view, using a macroeconomic model. At the same time, our evidence points toward the rejection of a competing alternative model also used extensively in the growth literature.

Second, despite the fact that Hall and Jones, Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare, and Bils and Klenow impose constant returns in production, a formal test rejected this hypothesis, sinceλ4is statistically signiÞcant6. To

check whether or not our model choice depends on ruling out constant returns, we have performed Box-Cox testing assuming constant returns beforehand. The Þnal choice of model is unaltered: we still do not reject the mincerian model although we do reject the MRW model.

4Although this induces measurement error in human capital, the problem is relatively small, since human capital changes

with a highly predictable pattern and the estimation technique used allows for regressors that are measured with error. To check the robustness of estimation results, we compared those using data withÞve-year intervals and those using yearly data. They were very close indeed.

5As for the initial capital stock, we followed Hall and Jones (1999) among many and approximated it byK0= I0/(gI + δ), whereK0is the initial capital stock,I0is the initial investment expenditure,gI is the growth rate of investment, and δis the depreciation rate of the capital stock. The latter was set equal to 9%, but results barely changed when we used different values forδ.

(6)

In Table 2 we present the estimates of parameters of the mincerian model, i.e., equation (4).

<include Table 2 here>

The reported estimates forα,φ,β, andgin Table 2 are close to what could be expecteda priori: several calibrated studies use a capital elasticity α = 1/3(see Cooley and Prescott (1995)). Estimates in Gollin (2002) are close to 0.43 for a variety of countries. As discussed above, φ can be interpreted as a measure of the percentage increase in income of an additional year of schooling. Mincerian regressions usually Þnd b

φ '10% (Mincer (1974)). Moreover, Psacharopolos (1994), who surveys schooling-return evidence using a large set of countries, Þnds an average of 6.8% for OECD countries and 10.1% for the world as a whole — very close to our estimate. An average growth rate of productivity of about 2.2% a year is in line with the evidence on long-run growth presented by Maddison (1995). Last, we perform a Wald test forln (Ai) =

ln (A),∀i, when estimating (4). Results overwhelmingly reject these restrictions (a p-value of 0.000), showing

that productivity indeed varies across countries.

Because we want to check the speciÞcation of our structural model, we performed a series of Sargan (1958) tests (equation-by-equation). If we take the signiÞcance level to be 5%, from a total of 95 country-regressions, 15 countries rejected the null in this test. This is about 16% of the sample of countries, a relatively low number. Although in terms of number of countries these rejections are relatively small, since the data for each country are weighted by the reciprocal of the standard deviation of its error term in computing estimates, it could happen that including these countries makes a big difference in terms of parameter estimates. To check if this was a potential problem, we ran mincerian regressions excluding from our sample of countries those for which we rejected orthogonality at the 5% level in the Sargan test. The results of this exercise showed overwhelmingly that estimates did not changed very much when these countries were excluded. For the restricted sample of countries, parameter estimates are the following: αb = 0.42, βb = 0.39, φb = 0.089, andgb= 0.029.

4

Conclusion

In this paper, we examined several features of the production functions used in the growth literature. The most relevant result is related to the form human capital should enter in the production function. Since the basic difference between the two most popular models used in theÞeld — the mincerian model and the Mankiw, Romer and Weil model — is whether human capital affects output exponentially or in levels, we propose here to distinguish between them by means of an econometric test based on the Box and Cox(1962) transformation. Contrary to the bulk of the previous empirical growth literature, we estimate directly the logarithmic version of the production function, which makes performing a Box-Cox test a direct exercise.

(7)

on microeconomic evidence, the results presented here validate their previous choice of production function from a formal econometric point of view. Moreover, our estimated coefficients are consistent with previous microeconomic evidence.

References

[1] Barro, R. and J. W. Lee, 1996. “International Measures of Schooling Years and Schooling Quality,” American Economic Review,86(2): 218-223.

[2] Bernanke, Ben S. and Gürkaynak, Refet S. 2001.“Is Growth Exogenous? Taking Mankiw, Romer and Weil Seriously,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2001, Ben S. Bernanke and Julio J. Rotemberg, Eds.Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 11-57.

[3] Bils, M. and P. Klenow 2000. “Does Schooling Causes Growth?,” American Economic Review,

90(5): 1160-1183.

[4] Box, G. E. P. and Cox, D. R. 1962. “An Analysis of Transformations,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B: 211-243.

[5] Cooley, T. and Prescott, E., 1995. “Economic Growth and Business Cycles,” in Cooley, T. and Prescott, E. (eds.), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, Princeton, Princeton University Press.

[6] Duffy, J. and C. Papageorgiou, 2000.“A Cross-Country Empiriacal Investigation of the Aggregate Production Function SpeciÞcation,” Journal of Economic Growth, 5(1): 87-120.

[7] Gollin, D., 2002.“Getting Income Shares Right: Self Employment, Unincorporated Enterprise, and the Cobb-Douglas Hypothesis,”Journal of Political Economy,110(2): 458-474.

[8] Hall, R.E. and C. Jones, 1999.“Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others?” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(February): 83-116.

[9] Hausman, Jerry A., 1978. “SpeciÞcation Tests in Econometrics,” Econometrica, 46: 1251-1272.

[10] Islam, N., 1995.“Growth Empirics: A Panel Data Approach,”Quarterly Journal of Economics,110: 1127-1170.

[11] Klenow, P. J. and A. Rodríguez-Clare, 1997.“The neoclassical revival in growth economics: has it gone too far?” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, Ben S. Bernanke and Julio J. Rotemberg, Eds. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 73-103.

[12] Mankiw, N. G., Romer, D. and D.Weil. 1992. “A Contribution To The Empirics of Economic Growth.”T he Quarterly Journal of Economics107(May): 407-437.

(8)

[14] Mincer, J., 1974. Schooling, Experience, and Earning, National Bureau of Economic Research, dis-tributed by Columbia University Press.

[15] Psacharopoulos, G., 1994.“Returns to Investment in Education: A Global Update,”World Devel-opment,22(9): 1325-1343.

[16] Sargan, J. D., 1958. “The Estimation of Economic Relationships using Instrumental Variables,” Econometrica, vol.26(3): 393-415.

(9)

Table 1: Estimates of the Models in Box-Cox Form Equation: lnyit= lnAi+λ1lnkit+ λ2

³

hθit−1

θ ´

+ λ3·t+λ4lnLit+ ηit

Estimated Parameters/(Std. Errors) Box-Cox Wald Test

λ1 λ2 λ3 θ λ4 θ= 1(p-value) θ= 0(p-value)

0.4285 0.0537 0.0098 0.8622 -0.1216 0.1657 0.0000

(0.0059) (0.0102) (0.0004) (0.0994) (0.0193)

Table 2: Estimates of the Mincerian Growth Model ( Log-Level Model)

Equation: lnyit= lnAi+ αlnkit+ βφhit+ βg·t+ (α+ β−1) lnLit+ ηit,

Estimated Parameters/(Std. Errors)

α φ g β

0.4306 0.0909 0.0221 0.4501

(10)

ENSAIOS ECONÔMICOS DA EPGE

458. DESEMPENHO DE ESTIMADORES DE VOLATILIDADE NA BOLSA DE VALORES DE SÃO

PAULO - Bernardo de Sá Mota; Marcelo Fernandes – Outubro de 2002 – 37 págs.

459. FOREIGN FUNDING TO AN EMERGING MARKET: THE MONETARY PREMIUM THEORY

AND THE BRAZILIAN CASE, 1991-1998 - Carlos Hamilton V. Araújo; Renato G. Flores Jr. –

Outubro de 2002 – 46 págs.

460. REFORMA PREVIDENCIÁRIA: EM BUSCA DE INCENTIVOS PARA ATRAIR O

TRABALHADOR AUTÔNOMO - Samantha Taam Dart; Marcelo Côrtes Neri; Flavio Menezes –

Novembro de 2002 – 28 págs.

461. DECENT WORK AND THE INFORMAL SECTOR IN BRAZIL – Marcelo Côrtes Neri –

Novembro de 2002 – 115 págs.

462. POLÍTICA DE COTAS E INCLUSÃO TRABALHISTA DAS PESSOAS COM DEFICIÊNCIA -

Marcelo Côrtes Neri; Alexandre Pinto de Carvalho; Hessia Guilhermo Costilla – Novembro de

2002 – 67 págs.

463. SELETIVIDADE E MEDIDAS DE QUALIDADE DA EDUCAÇÃO BRASILEIRA 1995-2001 -

Marcelo Côrtes Neri; Alexandre Pinto de Carvalho – Novembro de 2002 – 331 págs.

464. BRAZILIAN MACROECONOMICS WITH A HUMAN FACE: METROPOLITAN CRISIS,

POVERTY AND SOCIAL TARGETS – Marcelo Côrtes Neri – Novembro de 2002 – 61 págs.

465. POBREZA, ATIVOS E SAÚDE NO BRASIL - Marcelo Côrtes Neri; Wagner L. Soares –

Dezembro de 2002 – 29 págs.

466. INFLAÇÃO E FLEXIBILIDADE SALARIAL - Marcelo Côrtes Neri; Maurício Pinheiro –

Dezembro de 2002 – 16 págs.

467.

DISTRIBUTIVE EFFECTTS OF BRAZILIAN STRUCTURAL REFORMS - Marcelo Côrtes Neri;

José Márcio Camargo – Dezembro de 2002 – 38 págs.

468.

O TEMPO DAS CRIANÇAS - Marcelo Côrtes Neri; Daniela Costa – Dezembro de 2002 – 14

págs.

469.

EMPLOYMENT AND PRODUCTIVITY IN BRAZIL IN THE NINETIES - José Márcio Camargo;

Marcelo Côrtes Neri; Maurício Cortez Reis – Dezembro de 2002 – 32 págs.

470. THE ALIASING EFFECT, THE FEJER KERNEL AND TEMPORALLY AGGREGATED LONG

MEMORY PROCESSES - Leonardo R. Souza – Janeiro de 2003 – 32 págs.

471. CUSTO DE CICLO ECONÔMICO NO BRASIL EM UM MODELO COM RESTRIÇÃO A

CRÉDITO - Bárbara Vasconcelos Boavista da Cunha; Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira – Janeiro de

2003 – 21 págs.

472. THE COSTS OF EDUCATION, LONGEVITY AND THE POVERTY OF NATIONS - Pedro

Cavalcanti Ferreira; Samuel de Abreu Pessoa – Janeiro de 2003 – 31 págs.

(11)

Fevereiro de 2003 – 25 págs.

475. THE LONG-RUN ECONOMIC IMPACT OF AIDS - Pedro Cavalcanti G. Ferreira; Samuel de

Abreu Pessoa – Fevereiro de 2003 – 30 págs.

476. A MONETARY MECHANISM FOR SHARING CAPITAL: DIAMOND AND DYBVIG MEET

KIYOTAKI AND WRIGHT – Ricardo de O. Cavalcanti – Fevereiro de 2003 – 16 págs.

477.

INADA CONDITIONS IMPLY THAT PRODUCTION FUNCTION MUST BE ASYMPTOTICALLY

COBB-DOUGLAS - Paulo Barelli; Samuel de Abreu Pessoa – Março de 2003 – 4 págs.

478. TEMPORAL AGGREGATION AND BANDWIDTH SELECTION IN ESTIMATING LONG

MEMORY - Leonardo R. Souza - Março de 2003 – 19 págs.

479.

A NOTE ON COLE AND STOCKMAN - Paulo Barelli; Samuel de Abreu Pessoa – Abril de 2003

– 8 págs.

480. A

HIPÓTESE DAS EXPECTATIVAS NA ESTRUTURA A TERMO DE JUROS NO BRASIL:

UMA APLICAÇÃO DE MODELOS DE VALOR PRESENTE - Alexandre Maia Correia Lima;

João Victor Issler – Maio de 2003 – 30 págs.

481.

ON THE WELFARE COSTS OF BUSINESS CYCLES IN THE 20TH CENTURY - João Victor

Issler; Afonso Arinos de Mello Franco; Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho Guillén – Maio de 2003 –

29 págs.

482. RETORNOS ANORMAIS E ESTRATÉGIAS CONTRÁRIAS - Marco Antonio Bonomo; Ivana

Dall’Agnol – Junho de 2003 – 27 págs.

483. EVOLUÇÃO DA PRODUTIVIDADE TOTAL DOS FATORES NA ECONOMIA BRASILEIRA:

UMA ANÁLISE COMPARATIVA - Victor Gomes; Samuel de Abreu Pessoa;Fernando A .

Veloso – Junho de 2003 – 45 págs.

484.

MIGRAÇÃO, SELEÇÃO E DIFERENÇAS REGIONAIS DE RENDA NO BRASIL - Enestor da

Rosa dos Santos Junior; Naércio Menezes Filho; Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira – Junho de 2003 –

23 págs.

485. THE RISK PREMIUM ON BRAZILIAN GOVERNMENT DEBT, 1996-2002 - André Soares

Loureiro; Fernando de Holanda Barbosa - Junho de 2003 – 16 págs.

486. FORECASTING ELECTRICITY DEMAND USING GENERALIZED LONG MEMORY - Lacir

Jorge Soares; Leonardo Rocha Souza – Junho de 2003 – 22 págs.

487. USING

IRREGULARLY

SPACED RETURNS TO ESTIMATE MULTI-FACTOR MODELS:

APPLICATION TO BRAZILIAN EQUITY DATA - Álvaro Veiga; Leonardo Rocha Souza – Junho

de 2003 – 26 págs.

488. BOUNDS FOR THE PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION FUNCTION OF THE LINEAR ACD

PROCESS – Marcelo Fernandes – Julho de 2003 – 10 págs.

489. CONVEX COMBINATIONS OF LONG MEMORY ESTIMATES FROM DIFFERENT SAMPLING

RATES - Leonardo R. Souza; Jeremy Smith; Reinaldo C. Souza – Julho de 2003 – 20 págs.

(12)

PERIOD IN BRAZIL - Leonardo Rocha Souza; Lacir Jorge Soares – Julho de 2003 – 27 págs.

492. THE MISSING LINK: USING THE NBER RECESSION INDICATOR TO CONSTRUCT

COINCIDENT AND LEADING INDICES OF ECONOMIC ACTIVITY - JoãoVictor Issler; Farshid

Vahid – Agosto de 2003 – 26 págs.

493. REAL EXCHANGE RATE MISALIGNMENTS - Maria Cristina T. Terra; Frederico Estrella

Carneiro Valladares – Agosto de 2003 – 26 págs.

494. ELASTICITY OF SUBSTITUTION BETWEEN CAPITAL AND LABOR: A PANEL DATA

APPROACH - Samuel de Abreu Pessoa ; Silvia Matos Pessoa; Rafael Rob – Agosto de 2003 –

30 págs.

495. A

EXPERIÊNCIA DE CRESCIMENTO DAS ECONOMIAS DE MERCADO NOS ÚLTIMOS 40

ANOS – Samuel de Abreu Pessoa – Agosto de 2003 – 22 págs.

496.

NORMALITY UNDER UNCERTAINTY – Carlos Eugênio E. da Costa – Setembro de 2003 – 08

págs.

497.

RISK SHARING AND THE HOUSEHOLD COLLECTIVE MODEL - Carlos Eugênio E. da Costa

– Setembro de 2003 – 15 págs.

498.

REDISTRIBUTION WITH UNOBSERVED 'EX-ANTE' CHOICES - Carlos Eugênio E. da Costa

– Setembro de 2003 – 30 págs.

499. OPTIMAL

TAXATION WITH GRADUAL LEARNING OF TYPES - Carlos Eugênio E. da Costa –

Setembro de 2003 – 26 págs.

500.

AVALIANDO PESQUISADORES E DEPARTAMENTOS DE ECONOMIA NO BRASIL A

PARTIR DE CITAÇÕES INTERNACIONAIS - João Victor Issler; Rachel Couto Ferreira –

Setembro de 2003 – 29 págs.

501. A FAMILY OF AUTOREGRESSIVE CONDITIONAL DURATION MODELS - Marcelo

Fernandes; Joachim Grammig – Setembro de 2003 – 37 págs.

502. NONPARAMETRIC

SPECIFICATION TESTS FOR CONDITIONAL DURATION MODELS -

Marcelo Fernandes; Joachim Grammig – Setembro de 2003 – 42 págs.

503.

A NOTE ON CHAMBERS’S “LONG MEMORY AND AGGREGATION IN MACROECONOMIC

TIME SERIES” – Leonardo Rocha Souza – Setembro de 2003 – 11págs.

504. ON CHOICE OF TECHNIQUE IN THE ROBINSON-SOLOW-SRINIVASAN MODEL - M. Ali

Khan – Setembro de 2003 – 34 págs.

505. ENDOGENOUS

TIME-DEPENDENT RULES AND THE COSTS OF DISINFLATION WITH

IMPERFECT CREDIBILITY - Marco Bonomo; Carlos Viana de Carvalho – Outubro de 2003 –

27 págs.

506. CAPITAIS INTERNACIONAIS: COMPLEMENTARES OU SUBSTITUTOS? - Carlos Hamilton

V. Araújo; Renato G. Flôres Jr. – Outubro de 2003 – 24 págs.

Imagem

Table 2: Estimates of the Mincerian Growth Model ( Log-Level Model) Equation: ln y it = ln A i + α ln k it + βφh it + β g · t + (α + β − 1) ln L it + η it ,

Referências

Documentos relacionados

Segundo o relatório, para garantir o desenvolvimento humano sustentado sio imprescindrveis dois ingredientes : vigoroso crescimento econômico e uma estrutura de

The body dimension, growth, embryonic development time and fecundity obtained from life cycle studies are used in the secondary production calculations.. Materials

This study aimed at evaluating the efficacy of cinnamon, clove, oregano, and red pepper plant extracts as alternatives to antimicrobial growth promoters in broiler diets.. M ATERIAL

-se como casos impares a capela de Nossa Senhora da Consolação na Fig.12 Igreja Matriz de Loulé e na capela mor da Ermida de Nossa Senhora Fig.20 da Conceição de Alcoutim,

[569] Samuel de Abreu Pessˆoa, Pedro Cavalcanti Gomes Ferreira, e Fernando A.. On The Tyranny of Numbers: East Asian Miracles in

[569] Pedro Cavalcanti Gomes Ferreira, Samuel de Abreu Pessˆoa, e Fernando A.. On The Tyranny of Numbers: East Asian Miracles in

In empirical studies it was evidenced that functions related to accountancy, control, tax management, planning, elaboration and interpretation of reports, as shown in Chart 2,

Progress in software engineering requires (1) more empirical studies of quality, (2) increased focus on synthesizing evidence, (3) more theories to be built and tested, and (4)