• Nenhum resultado encontrado

Existence and uniqueness of a fixed-point for local contractions

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Share "Existence and uniqueness of a fixed-point for local contractions"

Copied!
30
0
0

Texto

(1)

❊♥s❛✐♦s ❊❝♦♥ô♠✐❝♦s

❊s❝♦❧❛ ❞❡

Pós✲●r❛❞✉❛çã♦

❡♠ ❊❝♦♥♦♠✐❛

❞❛ ❋✉♥❞❛çã♦

●❡t✉❧✐♦ ❱❛r❣❛s

✻✼✼

■❙❙◆ ✵✶✵✹✲✽✾✶✵

❊①✐st❡♥❝❡ ❛♥❞ ❯♥✐q✉❡♥❡ss ♦❢ ❛ ❋✐①❡❞✲P♦✐♥t

❢♦r ▲♦❝❛❧ ❈♦♥tr❛❝t✐♦♥s

▼❛✐♦ ❞❡ ✷✵✵✽

(2)

❖s ❛rt✐❣♦s ♣✉❜❧✐❝❛❞♦s sã♦ ❞❡ ✐♥t❡✐r❛ r❡s♣♦♥s❛❜✐❧✐❞❛❞❡ ❞❡ s❡✉s ❛✉t♦r❡s✳ ❆s

♦♣✐♥✐õ❡s ♥❡❧❡s ❡♠✐t✐❞❛s ♥ã♦ ❡①♣r✐♠❡♠✱ ♥❡❝❡ss❛r✐❛♠❡♥t❡✱ ♦ ♣♦♥t♦ ❞❡ ✈✐st❛ ❞❛

❋✉♥❞❛çã♦ ●❡t✉❧✐♦ ❱❛r❣❛s✳

❊❙❈❖▲❆ ❉❊ PÓ❙✲●❘❆❉❯❆➬➹❖ ❊▼ ❊❈❖◆❖▼■❆

❉✐r❡t♦r ●❡r❛❧✿ ❘✉❜❡♥s P❡♥❤❛ ❈②s♥❡

❉✐r❡t♦r ❞❡ ❊♥s✐♥♦✿ ❈❛r❧♦s ❊✉❣ê♥✐♦ ❞❛ ❈♦st❛

❉✐r❡t♦r ❞❡ P❡sq✉✐s❛✿ ▲✉✐s ❍❡♥r✐q✉❡ ❇❡rt♦❧✐♥♦ ❇r❛✐❞♦

❉✐r❡t♦r ❞❡ P✉❜❧✐❝❛çõ❡s ❈✐❡♥tí✜❝❛s✿ ❘✐❝❛r❞♦ ❞❡ ❖❧✐✈❡✐r❛ ❈❛✈❛❧❝❛♥t✐

❊①✐st❡♥❝❡ ❛♥❞ ❯♥✐q✉❡♥❡ss ♦❢ ❛ ❋✐①❡❞✲P♦✐♥t ❢♦r ▲♦❝❛❧

❈♦♥tr❛❝t✐♦♥s✴ ✱ ✕ ❘✐♦ ❞❡ ❏❛♥❡✐r♦ ✿ ❋●❱✱❊P●❊✱ ✷✵✶✶

✶ ♣✳ ✲ ✭❊♥s❛✐♦s ❊❝♦♥ô♠✐❝♦s❀ ✻✼✼✮

■♥❝❧✉✐ ❜✐❜❧✐♦❣r❛❢✐❛✳

(3)

❊①✐st❡♥❝❡ ❛♥❞ ❯♥✐q✉❡♥❡ss ♦❢ ❛ ❋✐①❡❞✲P♦✐♥t ❢♦r ▲♦❝❛❧

❈♦♥tr❛❝t✐♦♥s

❱❛✐❧❛❦✐s✱ ❨✐❛♥♥✐s

▼❛rt✐♥s✲❞❛✲❘♦❝❤❛✱ ❱✐❝t♦r ❋✐❧✐♣❡

▼❛✐♦ ❞❡ ✷✵✵✽

(4)

EXISTENCE AND UNIQUENESS OF A FIXED-POINT FOR LOCAL

CONTRACTIONS

V. F

ILIPE

M

ARTINS

-

DA

-R

OCHA AND

Y

IANNIS

V

AILAKIS

This paper proves the existence and uniqueness of a fixed-point for local contractions with-out assuming the family of contraction coefficients to be uniformly bounded away from 1. More importantly it shows how this fixed-point result can apply to study existence and unique-ness of solutions to some recursive equations that arise in economic dynamics.

KEYWORDS: Fixed-point theorem, Local contraction, Bellman operator, Koopmans operator, Thompson aggregator, Recursive utility.

1.

INTRODUCTION

Fixed-point results for local contractions turned out to be useful to solve

recur-sive equations in economic dynamics. Many applications in dynamic programming

are presented in Rincón-Zapatero and Rodríguez-Palmero (2003) for the

determin-istic case and in Matkowski and Nowak (2008) for the stochastic case.

Applica-tions to recursive utility problems can be found in Rincón-Zapatero and

Rodríguez-Palmero (2007). Previous fixed-point results for local contractions rely on a metric

approach.

1

The idea underlying this approach is based on the construction of a

met-ric that makes the local contraction a global contraction in a specific subspace. The

construction of an appropriate metric is achieved at the cost of restricting the family

of contraction coefficients to be uniformly bounded away from 1. Contrary to the

previous literature, we prove a fixed-point result using direct arguments that do not

require the application of the Banach Contraction Theorem for a specific metric. The

advantage of following this strategy of proof is that it allows us to deal with a

fam-ily of contraction coefficients that has a supremum equal to 1. In that respect, the

proposed fixed-point result generalizes the fixed-point results for local contractions

stated in the literature. An additional benefit is that the stated fixed-point

theo-rem applies to operators that are local contractions with respect to an uncountable

family of semi-distances.

We exhibit two applications to illustrate that, from an economic perspective, it

is important to have a fixed-point result that encompasses local contractions

asso-ciated with a family of contraction coefficients that are arbitrarily close to 1. The

first application deals with the existence and uniqueness of solutions to the Bellman

equation in the unbounded case, while the second one addresses the existence and

uniqueness of a recursive utility function derived from Thompson aggregators.

2

We

also present two applications to illustrate that, in some circumstances, it is relevant

not to restrict the cardinality of the family of semi-distances.

1See Zapatero and Rodríguez-Palmero (2003), Matkowski and Nowak (2008) and

Rincón-Zapatero and Rodríguez-Palmero (2009).

2Contrary to Blackwell aggregators, Thompson aggregators may not satisfy a uniform contraction

property. See Marinacci and Montrucchio (2007) for details.

(5)

The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 defines local contractions and states

a fixed-point theorem. Sections 3 and 4 show how the fixed-point result can apply

to the issue of existence and uniqueness of solutions to the Bellman and Koopmans

equations respectively. In section 5 we present two applications that give rise to local

contractions associated with an uncountable family of semi-distances. The proofs of

all theorems and propositions are postponed to Appendices.

2.

AN ABSTRACT FIXED-POINT THEOREM

In the spirit of Rincón-Zapatero and Rodríguez-Palmero (2007), we state a

fixed-point theorem for operators that are local contractions in an abstract space.

3

Let

F

be a set and

D

= (

d

j

)

jJ

be a family of semi-distances defined on

F

. We let

σ

be the

weak topology on

F

defined by the family

D

. A sequence

(

f

n

)

n∈N

is said

σ

-Cauchy

if it is

d

j

-Cauchy for each

j

J

. A subset

A

of

F

is said sequentially

σ

-complete if

every

σ

-Cauchy sequence in

A

converges in

A

for the

σ

-topology. A subset

A

F

is

said

σ

-bounded if diam

j

(

A

)

sup

{

d

j

(

f

,

g

)

:

f

,

g

A

}

is finite for every

j

J

.

D

EFINITION

2.1

Let

r

be a function from

J

to

J

. An operator

T

:

F

F

is a

local

contraction

with respect to

(

D

,

r

)

if for every

j

there exists

β

j

[

0, 1

)

such that

f

,

g

F

,

d

j

(

T f

,

T g

)

β

j

d

r(j)

(

f

,

g

)

.

The main technical contribution of this paper is the following existence and

uniqueness result of a fixed-point for local contractions.

T

HEOREM

2.1

Assume that the space F is

σ

-Hausdorff.

4

Consider a function r

:

J

J

and let T

:

F

F be a local contraction with respect to

(

D

,

r

)

. Consider a non-empty,

σ

-bounded, sequentially

σ

-complete and T -invariant subset A

F . If the following

condition is satisfied

(2.1)

j

J

,

lim

n→∞

β

j

β

r(j)

. . .

β

rn(j)

diam

rn+1(j)

(

A

) =

0

then the operator T admits a fixed-point f

in A. Moreover, if h

F satisfies

(2.2)

j

J

,

lim

n→∞

β

j

β

r(j)

. . .

β

rn(j)

d

rn+1(j)

(

h

,

A

) =

0

then the sequence

(

T

n

h

)

n∈N

is

σ

-convergent to f

.

5

The arguments of the proof of Theorem 2.1 are very simple and straightforward.

The details are postponed to Appendix A.

3From now on we should write RZ-RP (2003) for Rincón-Zapatero and Rodríguez-Palmero (2003),

RZ-RP (2007) for Zapatero and Rodríguez-Palmero (2007) and RZ-RP (2009) for Rincón-Zapatero and Rodríguez-Palmero (2009).

4That is, for each pairf,gF, iff 6=gthen there existsjJsuch thatd

j(f,g)>0.

5IfAis a non-empty subset ofFthen for eachhinF, we letd

(6)

R

EMARK

2.1

Theorem 2.1 generalizes a fixed-point existence result proposed in

Hadži´c (1979).

6

To be precise, Hadži´c (1979) imposed the additional requirement

that each semi-distance

d

j

is the restriction of a semi-norm defined on a vector space

E

containing

F

such that

E

is a locally convex topological vector space. Under such

conditions the existence result cannot be used for the two applications proposed in

Section 3 and Section 4. Moreover, Hadži´c (1979) does not provide any criteria of

stability similar to condition (2.2). A detailed comparison of Theorem 2.1 with the

result established in Hadži´c (1979) is presented in Appendix B.

R

EMARK

2.2

If

h

is a function in

A

then condition (2.2) is automatically satisfied,

implying that the fixed-point

f

is unique in

A

. Actually

f

is the unique fixed-point

on the set

B

F

defined by

B

§

h

F

:

j

J

,

lim

n→∞

β

j

β

r(j)

. . .

β

rn(j)

d

rn+1(j)

(

h

,

A

) =

0

ª

.

R

EMARK

2.3

If the function

r

is the identity, i.e.,

r

(

j

) =

j

then the operator

T

is

said to be a 0-local contraction and, in that case, conditions (2.1) and (2.2) are

automatically satisfied. In particular, if a fixed-point exists it is unique on the whole

space

F

.

R

EMARK

2.4

Assume that the space

F

is sequentially

σ

-complete and choose an

arbitrary

f

F

. As in RZ-RP (2007), we can show that the set

F

(

f

)

defined by

F

(

f

)

¦

g

F

:

j

J

,

d

j

(

g

,

f

)

[

1

/

(

1

β

j

)]

d

j

(

T f

,

f

)

©

is non-empty,

σ

-bounded,

σ

-closed and

T

-invariant. Applying Theorem 2.1 by

cho-osing

A

F

(

f

)

we obtain the following corollary.

C

OROLLARY

2.1

Let T

:

F

F be a

0

-local contraction with respect to a family

D

= (

d

j

)

jJ

of semi-distances. Assume that the space F is sequentially

σ

-complete.

Then the operator T admits a unique fixed-point f

in F . Moreover, for any arbitrary

f

F the sequence

(

T

n

f

)

n∈N

is

σ

-convergent to f

.

Corollary 2.1 is a generalization of a result first stated in RZ-RP (2003) (see

Theorem 1).

7

Unfortunately, the proposed proof in RZ-RP (2003) is not correct. As

Matkowski and Nowak (2008) have shown, an intermediate step (Proposition 1b)

used in their method of proof is false. RZ-RP (2009) have provided a corrigendum

of their fixed-point result but at the cost of assuming that the family

(

β

j

)

jJ

of

contraction coefficients is uniformly bounded away from 1, i.e., sup

jJ

β

j

<

1.

8

6We are grateful to a referee for pointing out this reference.

7If the familyJ is assumed to be countable then Corollary 2.1 coincides with Theorem 1 in

RZ-RP (2007).

8Matkowski and Nowak (2008) also prove a similar fixed-point result under this additional

(7)

From an economic perspective, the main contribution of this paper is to show

that it is important to establish a fixed-point theorem that allows the contraction

coefficients to be arbitrarily closed to 1. The economic applications presented in

Section 3 and Section 4 aim to illustrate this fact.

An additional difference of Theorem 2.1 with respect to the fixed-point results

of Matkowski and Nowak (2008) and RZ-RP (2009) is that the family

J

is not

as-sumed to be countable. Although in many applications it is sufficient to consider

a countable family of semi-distances, in some circumstances, it may be helpful not

to restrict the cardinality of the family of semi-distances. Two applications are

pre-sented in Section 5.

R

EMARK

2.5

An interesting observation about Theorem 2.1 is that its proof only

requires each

β

j

to be non-negative. The requirement that

β

j

belongs to

[

0, 1

)

is

used only in the proof of Corollary 2.1.

3.

DYNAMIC PROGRAMMING: UNBOUNDED BELOW CASE

We propose to consider the framework of Section 3.3 in RZ-RP (2003). The state

space is

X

R

+

, there is a technological correspondence

Γ

:

X

X

, a return

function

U

: gph

Γ

Z

[

−∞

,

)

where gph

Γ

is the graph of

Γ

and

β

(

0, 1

)

is

the discounting factor. Given

x

0

X

, we denote by

Π(

x

0

)

the set of all admissible

paths

e

x

= (

x

t

)

t¾0

defined by

Π(

x

0

)

≡ {

e

x

= (

x

t

)

t¾0

:

t

¾

0,

x

t+1

Γ(

x

t

)

}

.

The dynamic optimization problem consists of solving the following maximization

problem:

v

(

x

0

)

sup

{

S

(

e

x

)

:

e

x

Π(

x

0

)

}

where

S

(

e

x

)

X

t¾0

β

t

U

(

x

t

,

x

t+1

)

.

We denote by

C

(

X

,

Z

)

the space of continuous functions from

X

to

Z

, and we let

C

(

X

)

be the space of functions

f

in

C

(

X

,

Z

)

such that the restriction of

f

to

X

X

\ {

0

}

takes values in

R

. Among others, we make the following assumptions.

DP1.

The correspondence

Γ

is continuous with nonempty and compact values.

DP2.

The function

U

: gph

(Γ)

[

−∞

,

)

is continuous on gph

(Γ)

.

DP3.

There is a continuous function

q

:

X

X

with

(

x

,

q

(

x

))

gph

Γ

and

U

(

x

,

q

(

x

))

>

−∞

for all

x

X

.

We denote by

B

the Bellman operator defined on

C

(

X

,

Z

)

as follows:

B

f

(

x

)

sup

{

U

(

x

,

y

) +

β

f

(

y

)

:

y

Γ(

x

)

}

.

(8)

function

v

coincides with the fixed-point of the Bellman operator

B

. To establish

this relationship, we introduce the following assumptions.

9

DP4.

There exist three functions

w

,

w

+

, and

w

in

C

(

X

)

such that

w

w

+

<

w

and

w

w

w

+

w

=

O

(

1

)

at 0

together with

(a)

B

w

<

w

,

B

w

¾

w

,

B

w

+

w

+

(b)

(

w

+

w

)

/

(

B

w

w

) =

O

(

1

)

at 0

(c)

for any

x

0

X

, the set

Π

0

(

x

0

)

is non-empty

10

and for each admissible

path

e

x

= (

x

t

)

t¾0

in

Π

0

(

x

0

)

it follows that

lim

t→∞

β

t

w

(

x

t

) =

0

and

t

lim

→∞

β

t

w

+

(

x

t

) =

0.

DP5.

There exists a countable increasing family

(

K

j

)

j∈N

of non-empty and compact

subsets of

X

such that for any compact subset

K

of

X

, there exists

j

with

K

K

j

and such that

Γ(

K

j

)

K

j

for all

j

N

.

We denote by

[

w

,

w

+

]

the order interval in

C

(

X

)

, i.e., the space of all functions

f

C

(

X

)

satisfying

w

f

w

+

. The following theorem is analogous to the main

result of Section 3.3 (see Theorem 6) in RZ-RP (2003).

11

T

HEOREM

3.1

Assume (DP1)–(DP5). Then the following statements hold:

(a)

The Bellman equation has a unique solution f in

[

w

,

w

+

]

C

(

X

)

.

(b)

The value function v

is continuous in X

and coincides with the fixed-point f .

(c)

For any function g in

[

w

,

w

+

]

, the sequence

(

B

n

g

)

n∈N

converges to v

for the

topology associated with the family

(

d

j

)

j∈N

of semi-distances defined on the space

[

w

,

w

+

]

by

d

j

(

f

,

g

)

sup

xK⋆

j

ln

f

w

w

+

w

(

x

)

ln

g

w

w

+

w

(

x

)

where K

j

=

K

j

\ {

0

}

.

Using the convexity property of the Bellman operator, RZ-RP (2003) proved (refer

to page 1553) that the operator

B

is a 0-local contraction with respect to the family

(

d

j

)

j∈N

where the contraction coefficient

β

j

is defined by

β

j

1

exp

{−

µ

j

}

with

µ

j

sup

{

d

j

(

f

,

B

w

)

:

f

[

w

,

w

+

]

}

.

9Given two functionsf andginC(X)withg(x)6=0 in a neighborhood of 0, we say thatf/g=O(1)

atx=0 if there exists a neighborhoodVof 0 inXsuch thatf/gis bounded inV\ {0}.

10Π0(x

0)is the subset ofΠ(x0)of all admissible pathsexinΠ(x0)such thatS(ex)exists and satisfies S(ex)>−∞.

11Our set of assumptions is slightly different from the one used by RZ-RP (2003). In particular

con-dition DP4(b) is not imposed in RZ-RP (2003). We make this assumption to ensure that the distance

(9)

Observe that for each

j

and each pair of functions

f

,

g

in

[

w

,

w

+

]

we have

d

j

(

f

,

g

) =

sup

xK⋆

j

ln

f

w

g

w

(

x

)

implying that

µ

j

=

max

§

ln

θ

+

K

j

,

ln

θ

K

j

ª

where

θ

+

(

w

w

+

)

/

(

w

− B

w

)

and

θ

(

w

w

)

/

(

w

− B

w

)

.

12

Since the family

(

K

j

)

j∈N

covers the space

X

, we get

sup

jJ

µ

j

=

max

¦

ln

θ

+

X⋆

,

ln

θ

X⋆

©

.

If either the function ln

θ

+

or the function ln

θ

is unbounded, then the supremum

sup

jJ

β

j

of the contraction coefficients is 1. In this case, the fixed-point results

of Matkowski and Nowak (2008) and RZ-RP (2009) cannot apply to prove

The-orem 3.1. In contrast, TheThe-orem 2.1 makes possible to provide a straightforward

proof of Theorem 3.1. To illustrate that it is possible to exhibit economic

applica-tions that give rise to an unbounded sequence

(

µ

j

)

jJ

we borrow two examples

from RZ-RP (2003).

3.1.

Logarithmic utility function and technology with decreasing returns

We consider Example 10 in RZ-RP (2003). Fix a function

F

:

[

0,

)

R

con-tinuous and strictly increasing with

F

(

0

) =

0. Moreover, assume that there exists

x

>

0 with

F

(

x

) =

x

,

F

(

x

)

>

x

for all

x

<

x

and

F

(

x

)

<

x

for all

x

>

x

. We

consider the Bellman operator where the action space

X

is

R

+

; the correspondence

Γ

is defined by

Γ(

x

) = [

0,

F

(

x

)]

for all

x

X

; and the utility function

U

is defined

by

U

(

x

,

y

) =

ln

(

F

(

x

)

y

)

for all

(

x

,

y

)

gph

Γ

.

We follow RZ-RP (2003) and pose

w

(

x

) =

1

(

1

β

)

2

ln

1

2

+

1

1

β

ln

x

if

x

x

1

(

1

β

)

2

ln

1

2

+

1

1

β

ln

x

if

x

>

x

.

There exists

σ >

0 small enough such that

x

1−σ

x

σ

¾

F

(

x

)

for every

x

in

[

0,

x

]

. We

then pose

w

+

(

x

) =

σ

1

βσ

ln

x

+

1

σ

(

1

β

)(

1

βσ

)

ln

x

if

x

x

1

1

β

ln

x

if

x

>

x

.

12Iff is a function inC(X,Y)andKis a subset ofX, we letf

(10)

Finally, the function

w

is defined by

w

(

x

) =

a

+ (

1

β

)

−1

ln

x

if

x

x

and

w

(

x

) =

a

+

w

+

(

x

)

if

x

¾

x

where

a

>

0. We claim that the sequence

(

µ

j

)

jJ

is not bounded.

P

ROPOSITION

3.1

We have

lim inf

x→∞

θ

+

(

x

) =

0

or

lim sup

x→∞

θ

(

x

) =

.

P

ROOF OF

P

ROPOSITION

3.1:

We denote by

ξ

the function in

C

(

X

)

defined by

ξ

w

− B

w

. For each

x

X

we have

ξ

(

x

)

>

0. We split the proof in two cases. First

we assume that there exists

M

(

0,

)

such that

ξ

(

x

)

M

for

x

large enough.

Observe that for every

x

¾

x

we have

θ

(

x

) =

1

ξ

(

x

)

a

+

1

1

β

ln

x

w

(

x

)

.

This implies that lim

x→∞

θ

(

x

) =

.

Assume now that lim sup

x→∞

ξ

(

x

) =

. For every

x

¾

x

we have

θ

+

(

x

) =

a

(

x

)

implying that lim inf

x→∞

θ

+

(

x

) =

0.

Q.E.D.

3.2.

Homogenous utility function and technology with decreasing returns

We consider Example 11 in RZ-RP (2003). There is a function

F

:

[

0,

)

R

strictly increasing and continuously differentiable on

(

0,

)

with

F

(

0

) =

0 and

F

(

0

+

)

>

1. Moreover, there exists

x

>

0 with

F

(

x

) =

x

and

F

(

x

)

<

x

for all

x

>

x

. We consider the Bellman operator where the action space

X

is

R

+

; the

correspondence

Γ

is defined by

Γ(

x

) = [

0,

F

(

x

)]

for all

x

X

; the utility function

U

is defined by

U

(

x

,

y

) = (

F

(

x

)

y

)

θ

for all

(

x

,

y

)

gph

Γ

where

θ <

0.

We follow RZ-RP (2003) and pose

w

0 and

w

+

ψ

where

ψ

≡ B

0. In this

example we have

ψ

(

x

) =

F

(

x

)

θ

. There exists

x

1

(

0,

x

)

such that

x

<

F

(

x

)

for every

x

x

1

. Then we pose

w

(

x

)

(

1

β

)

−1

(

F

(

x

)

x

)

θ

if

x

x

1

and

w

(

x

)

w

(

x

1

)

if

x

¾

x

1

. We claim that the sequence

(

µ

j

)

jJ

is not bounded when

F

is unbounded.

P

ROPOSITION

3.2

If

F

is unbounded then lim

x→∞

θ

(

x

) =

.

P

ROOF OF

P

ROPOSITION

3.2:

Observe that for this example we have

θ

=

w

. It

follows that for all

x

¾

x

1

θ

(

x

) =

(

F

(

x

1

)

x

1

)

θ

1

β

F

(

x

)

θ

.

Since

F

is not bounded, we must have lim

x→∞

F

(

x

) =

and we get the desired

(11)

4.

RECURSIVE PREFERENCES FOR THOMPSON AGGREGATORS

Consider a model where an agent chooses consumption streams in the space

+

of non-negative and bounded sequences

x

= (

x

t

)

t∈N

with

x

t

¾

0. The space

is endowed with the sup-norm

k

x

k

sup

{|

x

t

|

:

t

N

}

. We propose to

investi-gate whether it is possible to represent the agent’s preference relation on

+

by a

recursive utility function derived from an aggregator

W

:

X

×

Y

Y

where

X

=

R

+

and

Y

=

R

+

. The answer obviously depends on the assumed

proper-ties of the aggregator function

W

.

After the seminal contribution of Lucas and Stokey (1984), there has been a wide

literature dealing with the issue of existence and uniqueness of a recursive

util-ity function derived from aggregators that satisfy a uniform contraction property

(Blackwell aggregators). We refer to Becker and Boyd III (1997) for an excellent

ex-position of this literature.

13

In what follows we explore whether a unique recursive

utility function can be derived from Thompson aggregators.

Throughout this section, we assume that

W

satisfies the following conditions:

A

SSUMPTION

4.1

W

is a Thompson aggregator as defined by Marinacci and

Mon-trucchio (2007), i.e., the following conditions are satisfied:

W1.

The function

W

is continuous, non-negative, non-decreasing and satisfies the

condition

W

(

0, 0

) =

0.

W2.

There exists a continuous function

f

:

X

Y

such that

W

(

x

,

f

(

x

))

f

(

x

)

.

14

W3.

The function

W

is concave in the second variable at 0.

15

W4.

For every

x

>

0 we have

W

(

x

, 0

)

>

0.

R

EMARK

4.1

We can find in Marinacci and Montrucchio (2007) a list of

exam-ples of Thompson aggregators that do not satisfy a uniform contraction property.

For instance, one may consider

W

(

x

,

y

) = (

x

η

+

β

y

σ

)

1

where

η

,

σ

,

ρ

,

β >

0

together with the following conditions:

σ <

1 and either

σ < ρ

or

σ

=

ρ

and

β <

1. Another example is the aggregator introduced by Koopmans, Diamond, and

Williamson (1964):

W

(

x

,

y

) = (

1

)

ln

(

1

+

η

x

δ

+

β

y

)

with

θ

,

β

,

δ

,

η >

0. This

aggregator is always Thompson but it is Blackwell only if

β < θ

.

In order to define formally the concept of a recursive utility function we need

to introduce some notations. We denote by

π

the linear functional from

to

R

13See also: Epstein and Zin (1989), Boyd III (1990), Duran (2000), Duran (2003), Le Van and Vailakis

(2005) and Rincón-Zapatero and Rodríguez-Palmero (2007).

14Marinacci and Montrucchio (2007) assume that there is a sequence(xn,yn)

n∈NinR2+with(x

n) n∈N

increasing to infinite andW(xn,yn)ynfor eachn. This assumption, together with the others, implies

that for eachxX, there existsyxYsuch thatW(x,yxyx. We require that we can choosex7→yx

continuous.

(12)

defined by

π

x

=

x

0

for every

x

= (

x

t

)

tN

in

. We denote by

σ

the operator of

defined by

σ

x

= (

x

t+1

)

tN

.

D

EFINITION

4.1

Let

X

be a subset of

stable under the shift operator

σ

.

16

A

function

u

:

X

R

is a

recursive utility function

on

X

if

x

X

,

u

(

x

) =

W

(

π

x

,

u

(

σ

x

))

.

We propose to show that we can use the Thompson metric introduced by

Thomp-son (1963) to prove the existence of a continuous recursive utility function when

the space

X

is the subset of all sequences in

+

which are uniformly bounded away

from 0, i.e.,

X

≡ {

x

: inf

t∈N

x

t

>

0

}

.

17

The topology on

X

derived from the

sup-norm is denoted by

τ

. This space of feasible consumption patterns also appears

in Boyd III (1990).

4.1.

The operator

In the spirit of Marinacci and Montrucchio (2007) we introduce the following

operator. First, denote by

V

the space of sequences

V

= (

v

t

)

t∈N

where

v

t

is a

τ

-continuous function from

X

to

R

+

. The real number

v

t

(

x

)

is interpreted as the

utility at time

t

derived from the consumption stream

x

X

. For each sequence of

functions

V

= (

v

s

)

s∈N

and each period

t

, we denote by

[

T V

]

t

the function from

X

to

R

+

defined by

x

X

,

[

T V

]

t

(

x

)

W

(

x

t

,

v

t+1

(

x

))

.

Since

W

and

v

t+1

are continuous the function

[

T V

]

t

is continuous. In particular,

the mapping

T

is an operator on

V

, i.e.,

T

(

V

)

⊂ V

.

We denote by

K

the family of all sets

K

= [

a

1

,

b

1

]

with 0

<

a

<

b

<

.

18

We

consider the subspace

F

of

V

composed of all sequences

V

such that on every set

K

= [

a

1

,

b

1

]

∈ K

the family

V

= (

v

t

)

t∈N

is uniformly bounded from above and

away from 0, i.e.,

V

= (

v

t

)

t∈N

belongs to

F

if for every 0

<

a

<

b

<

there exist

v

and

v

such that

t

N

,

x

[

a

1

,

b

1

]

,

0

<

v

v

t

(

x

)

v

<

.

Observe that

T

maps

F

into

F

since

W

is monotone with respect to both variables.

19

The objective is to show that

T

admits a unique fixed-point

V

in

F

. The reason is

that if

V

= (

v

t

)

t∈N

is a fixed-point of

T

then the function

v

0

is a recursive utility

16I.e., for every

x∈Xwe haveσxstill belongs toX.

17See also Montrucchio (1998) for another reference where the Thompson metric is used. 18We denote by1the sequence

x= (xt)t∈Nin∞defined byxt=1 for everyt. The order interval

[a1,b1]is the set{x∈+:axtb,∀t∈N}.

19We can easily check that for everyV= (v

t)t∈NinFand for everyK≡[a1,b1], we haveW(a,v

(13)

function. Indeed, we will show that for each consumption stream

x

X

and every

time

t

, we have lim

n→∞

[

T

n

0

]

t

(

x

) =

v

t

(

x

)

. Since

[

T

n

0

]

t

(

σ

x

) = [

T

n

0

]

t+1

(

x

)

and

[

T

n

0

]

t

(

x

) =

W

(

x

t

,

W

(

x

t+1

, . . . ,

W

(

x

t+n

, 0

)

. . .

))

,

passing to the limit we get that

v

t

(

σ

x

) =

v

t+1

(

x

)

. This property is crucial in order

to prove that

v

0

is a recursive utility on

X

. Indeed, we have

v

0

(

x

) = [

T V

]

0

(

x

) =

W

(

x

0

,

v

1

(

x

)) =

W

(

x

0

,

v

0

(

σ

x

))

.

20

4.2.

The Thompson metric

Fix a set

K

in

K

. We propose to introduce the semi-distance

d

K

on

F

defined as

follows:

21

d

K

(

V

,

V

)

max

{

ln

M

K

(

V

|

V

)

, ln

M

K

(

V

|

V

)

}

where

M

K

(

V

|

V

)

inf

{

α >

0 :

x

K

,

t

N

,

v

t

(

x

)

α

v

t

(

x

)

}

.

Let

V

∈ V

be the sequence of functions

(

v

t

)

t∈N

defined by

v

t

(

x

)

f

(

k

x

k

)

.

Observe that

[

T V

]

t

(

x

)

v

t

(

x

)

for every

t

N

and every

x

in

X

. We

de-note by

V

0

the sequence of functions

T

0

= ([

T

0

]

t

)

tN

, i.e.,

V

0

= (

v

t0

)

t∈N

with

v

t0

(

x

) =

W

(

x

t

, 0

)

. The monotonicity of

T

then implies that

T

maps the order

in-terval

[

V

0

,

V

]

into

[

V

0

,

V

]

. Moreover, both

V

0

and

V

belong to

F

.

22

We can

then adapt the arguments of Theorem 9 in (Marinacci and Montrucchio, 2007,

Ap-pendix B) to show that

T

is a 0-local contraction on

[

V

0

,

V

]

with respect to the

family

D

= (

d

K

)

K∈K

. More precisely, we can prove that

d

K

(

T V

,

T V

)

β

K

d

K

(

V

,

V

)

where

β

K

1

[

µ

K

]

−1

and

µ

K

M

K

(

V

|

V

0

)

. Recall that

M

K

(

V

|

V

0

)

inf

{

α >

0 :

x

K

,

t

N

,

f

(

k

x

k

)

α

W

(

x

t

, 0

)

}

implying that

µ

K

=

sup

x∈K

sup

t∈N

f

(

k

x

k

)

W

(

x

t

, 0

)

=

sup

x∈K

f

(

k

x

k

)

inf

t∈N

W

(

x

t

, 0

)

=

f

(

b

)

W

(

a

, 0

)

.

The set

[

V

0

,

V

]

is sequentially complete with respect to the family

D

.

23

Therefore,

we can apply Corollary 2.1 to get the existence of a unique fixed-point

V

= (

v

t

)

t∈N

20Observe that the timetutilityv

t(x)of the consumption streamxdoes not depend on the past

consumption sincev⋆t(x) =vt1(σx) =. . .=v0(σtx).

21The functiond

Kis well-defined, we refer to Appendix D for details. 22See Appendix D for details.

(14)

of

T

in

[

V

0

,

V

]

.

24

The function

u

v

0

:

X

R

+

is then a recursive utility function

associated with the aggregator

W

and continuous for the sup-norm topology.

25

We

have thus provided a sketch of the proof of the following result.

26

T

HEOREM

4.1

Given a Thompson aggregator W , there exists a recursive utility

func-tion u

:

X

R

which is continuous on

X

for the sup-norm. Moreover, this function is

unique among all continuous functions which are bounded on every order interval of

K

.

R

EMARK

4.2

In the spirit of Kreps and Porteus (1978), Epstein and Zin (1989), Ma

(1998), Marinacci and Montrucchio (2007) and Klibanoff, Marinacci, and Mukerji

(2009), we can adapt the arguments above in order to deal with uncertainty.

R

EMARK

4.3

Consider the KDW aggregator

W

(

x

,

y

) = (

1

)

ln

(

1

+

η

x

δ

+

β

y

)

for any

θ

,

β

,

δ

,

η >

0. Applying Theorem 4.1 we get the existence of a recursive

utility function defined on

X

and continuous for the sup-norm. When

β < θ

the

aggregator

W

is Blackwell and the existence of a continuous recursive utility

func-tion can be established by applying the Continuous Existence Theorem in Boyd III

(1990) or Becker and Boyd III (1997). We propose to show that the case

β

¾

θ

is not covered by the Continuous Existence Theorem. Observe first that the lowest

α >

0 satisfying the uniform Lipschitz condition

|

W

(

x

,

y

)

W

(

x

,

y

)

|

α

|

y

y

|

for all

x

>

0 and

y

,

y

¾

0, is

α

=

β/θ

. Assume by way of contradiction that

the conditions of the Continuous Existence Theorem are met. Then there exists a

positive continuous function

ϕ

:

X

(

0,

)

such that

M

sup

x∈X

W

(

π

x

, 0

)

ϕ

(

x

)

<

and

χ

sup

x∈X

α

ϕ

(

σ

x

)

ϕ

(

x

)

<

1.

For every

x

X

and every

n

¾

1, we obtain

α

n

W

(

x

n

, 0

)

M

α

n

ϕ

(

σ

n

x

)

M

α

ϕ

(

σ

n

x

)

ϕ

(

σ

n−1

x

)

×

. . .

×

α

ϕ

(

σ

x

)

ϕ

(

x

)

ϕ

(

x

)

M

χ

n

ϕ

(

x

)

.

24Observe that the family of contraction coefficients is such that sup

K∈KβK=1. We will show that

uniqueness is obtained on the whole setF.

25Observe thatuis non-decreasing. This follows from the fact that

u⋆(x) = lim

(15)

Choosing

x

=

a

1

for any

a

>

0, we get

n

¾

1,

α

n

W

(

a

, 0

)

M

χ

n

ϕ

(

a

1

)

.

Since

α

¾

1 and

χ <

1, it follows that

W

(

a

, 0

) =

0 for every

a

>

0: contradiction.

5.

RECURSIVE PREFERENCES FOR BLACKWELL AGGREGATORS

We borrow the notations of Section 4 and consider a model where an agent

chooses consumption streams in the space

+

. We propose to investigate if it is

possible to represent the agent’s preference relation on

+

by a recursive utility

function derived from an aggregator

W

:

X

×

Y

Y

where

X

=

R

+

and

Y

is a

subset of

[

−∞

,

)

containing 0. The answer will obviously depend on the

proper-ties the aggregator

W

satisfies. Throughout this section, we will assume that

W

is a

Blackwell aggregator, i.e.,

W

is continuous on

X

×

Y

, non-decreasing on

X

×

Y

and

satisfies a Lipschitz condition with respect to its second argument, i.e., there exists

δ

(

0, 1

)

such that

|

W

(

x

,

y

)

W

(

x

,

y

)

|

δ

|

y

y

|

,

x

X

,

y

,

y

Y

.

The objective is to find a subspace

X

+

stable under

σ

such that

W

admits a

recursive utility function from

X

to

R

.

Taking

as the commodity space is a choice that is made in many intertemporal

models.

27

The advantage of

with respect to other spaces (for instance

p

with

1

p

<

) is that it does not impose severe restrictions on the kind of dynamics

that can be considered (see Chapter 15 in Stockey, Lucas, and Prescott (1989) for

a discussion). In addition, the existence of a non-empty interior for

+

simplifies

considerably the application of a separation theorem that underlies the theorems of

welfare economics in an intertemporal setting (see Lucas and Prescott (1971)).

The choice of

as a commodity space introduces some complications on the

choice of the appropriate topology. One may consider several topologies on

.

There is the topology derived from the sup-norm and the product topology. There

are also the weak topology

σ

(

,

1

)

, the Mackey topology

τ

(

,

1

)

and the

abso-lute weak topology

|

σ

|

(

,

1

)

which is defined as the smallest locally convex-solid

topology on

consistent with the duality

,

1

.

28

In particular we have (see

Page 292 in Aliprantis and Border (1999))

σ

(

,

1

)

⊂ |

σ

|

(

,

1

)

τ

(

,

1

)

.

27See among others Lucas and Prescott (1971), Bewley (1972), Kehoe, Levine, and Romer (1990),

Magill and Quinzii (1994), Levine and Zame (1996) and Alipranits, Border, and Burkinshaw (1997). In some models this choice is imposed directly while in some others it is implied by the assumptions made on the production activity.

28This family is the weak topology generated by the family of semi-norms{η

q: q∈

1}where

∀x∈∞, ηq=〈|x|,|q|〉=

X

t∈N

Referências

Documentos relacionados

Qin and Rivera ([16]) established the global existence, uniqueness and exponential stability of solutions to equations of one-dimensional nonlinear thermoelasticity with

The structure of the remelting zone of the steel C90 steel be- fore conventional tempering consitute cells, dendritic cells, sur- rounded with the cementite, inside of

Corpo em alumínio injetado e tampa em chapa de aço Nesta outra solução, temos um corpo em alumínio injetado (1) e posteriormente maquinado conforme especificação

A SÁTIRA DEPOIS DA MORTE: um testamento em verso do Governador Luís Baía Monteiro, o Onça.. Luís Baía1 Monteiro, Governador do Rio de Janeiro entre 1725 e 1732, ficou para a

In this presentation, I will describe the HiDimDA (High Dimensional Discriminant Analysis) R package, available on CRAN, that implements several routines and

Os Espaços Internet do concelho de Reguengos de Monsaraz e o Programa Escolhas através do Centro de Inclusão Digital são os locais onde os reguenguenses ciganos têm

Hernández, Existence and uniqueness of positive solutions for some quasilinear elliptic problems, Nonlinear Anal. Zumpano, Existence of positive radial solutions for the n

The probability of attending school four our group of interest in this region increased by 6.5 percentage points after the expansion of the Bolsa Família program in 2007 and