• Nenhum resultado encontrado

Stabilization, volatility and the equilibrium real exchange rate

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Stabilization, volatility and the equilibrium real exchange rate"

Copied!
32
0
0

Texto

(1)

,

...

~DAÇÃO

GETUUO VARGAS

Praia de Botafogo, nO 190/10" andar - Rio de Janeiro - 22253-900

Seminários de Pesquisa Econômica 11 (2

a

parte)

11

STABlLlZATlON,

VOI,ATILITY

AND THE

EQUILlBRIDM REAl

I

EXCHANGE RATE

11

CRISTINA

TERRA

(2)

[l I

LJL7 ()

T E C A

I

' A ~ n. "J' ':'~ ~ ~I:: :: ;,iQ N S E N , ,,"~~! li ,f,GAS __ , __ ~ .,~ ~'O',.,_M_-'

I

• ~ L . -; '; (; : , .:

(3)

Abstract

Preliminar")!

C omments We lcome

Stabilization, Volatilitv, and

the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate*

by

Gustavo M. Gonzaga

Maria Cristina T. Terra

PUC-Rio

In a general equilibrium model. we show that the value 01' the equilibrium real exchange rate is affected by its own volatility. Risk averse exporters. that make their exporting decision before observing the realization of the real exchange rate. choose to export less the more volatile is the real exchange rate. Therefore the trude balance and the variance of the real exchange rate are negatively related. An increase in the volatility of the real exchange rate. for instance. deteriorates the trade balance. and to restore equilibrium a real exchange rate depreciation has to take place. In the empirical part of the paper. we use the traditional (unconditional) standard deviation of RER changes as our measure 01' RER volatility. \Ve describe the behavior 01' the RER \'olatility for Brazil. Argentina and Mexico. \lonthly data for the three countries are used. and also daily data for Bruzil. Interesting patterns

01'

volatility could be associated to the nature

01'

the several stabilization plans adopted in those countries. and to changes in the exchange rate regimes .

• \Ve thank Carlos \\'inograd. Afonso Bevilaqua. Dionísio Dias Carneiro. Ruy Monteiro. Ylauricio Cardenas. and participants at the International Economcs Workshop as PUC-Rio for useful commnents and suggestions, \\'e also thank Cristiana Aguiar for research assistance, \\'e c1aim total responsibility for any remammg errors.

(4)

1. Introduction

, There is a large theoretical and empirical literature on the etIects of real exchange

rate volatility on intemational trade (see Côté ( 1994) for a recent survey of the literature).

Traditional models consider risk averse exporters for whom the real exchange rate is the

source of uncertainty. Two assumptions are crucial for the volatility of the real exchange

rate to atIect the exporting decision. One is that there is no perfect hedging - access to

exchange rate forward market reduces the effect. The other is that exporters have to be

very risk averse. As Caballero and Corbo ( 1989) point out. protit is a convex function

01'

prices: hence increased variability of prices increases protits. To capture the behavior

01'

a risk averse agent facing risk. exporters are assumed to maximize a concave function of

profits. because a concave function has the property of decreasing with the variability of

its argument. Hence. exporters maximize a concave function (a utility function) of a

convex function (the profit function) of prices. They will ultimately be maximizing a

concave function of prices if the utility function is sufficiently concave. that is. if he is

sufficientlv risk averse.

One common feature

01'

alI models that relate the volatility

01'

the real exchange rate to trade is that they use a partial-equilibrium approach. They focus on the export

sector. and study the effect

01'

an exogenously given volatility

01'

the real exchange rate on the quantity

01'

exports. This paper tries to make a step into using a general equilibrium model. Substitution across sectors is considered. and the model allows the study of the

etIect of volatility on the equilibrium real exchange rate. that is. on the value

01'

the real exchange rate thar yields equilibrium in all markets of the economy. The volatility

01'

the real exchange rate is derived endogenously. lts original source in the model is a demand

(5)

This paper intends 10 make two points. The tirst one is that the value of the

equilibrium real exchange rate is affected by its own volatility. Risk averse exporters. that

make their exporting decision before observing the realization of the real exchange rate.

• ehoose to export less the more volatile is the real exchange rate. Therefore the trade

balance and the variance of the real exchange rate are negatively related. An increase in the

volatility of the real exchange rate. for instance, deteriorates the trade balance. and to

restore equilibrium a real exchange rate depreciation has to take place.

The other point this paper intends to stress is that price stabilization plans may

affect the variability of the real exchange rate. The effect on volatility is clear when the

price stabilization plan embodies a change in the exchange rate regime. Ifthe exchange rate

was tlexible before the plano and is fixed after the plan, for instance. then a lower volatility

of the real exchange rate should be expected. However. even if the exchange rate regime

remains unchanged. as in our model. price stabilization may affect the variance ofthe real

exchange rate. Price stabilization means that the intlation rate moves to a lower leveI. and

that may affect its variability. The different volatility of the intlation rate \vould then

affect the variability of the real exchange rate. The message this paper wants to convey is

that the \'ariability of the real exchange rate may affect its equilibrium leveI. and price

stabilization may atIeet that \'ariability.

11' our theoretical results are correct. empirical studies should include the real

exchange rate volatility as one of the explanatory variables 01' the real exchange rate itself. In the empirical part of the papeL we use the traditional (unconditional) standard

deviation 01' RER changes over some period as our measure 01' RER volatility. which is still the most \\'idely used mensure 01' volatility. Some recent empirical attempts have

(6)

estimated conditional variances using a GARCH model.\ One of the reasons to stick with

the traditional method is the presence of structural breaks associated \vith changes in the

exchange rate indexed regime that occurred in these countries over the period studied here.

These structural breaks probably altered the autoregressive coefficients

01'

the GARCH approach in a way hard to be detected in the data. since there are not toa many

observations in each regime. As the effects of these structural breaks are our main object

of study in this paper. we decided not to use conditional variances at this time.

The empirical section consists of a description of the behavior of the RER

volatility for Brazil. Argentina and Mexico. We used monthly data for the three countries.

and also daily data for Brazil. Interesting patterns of volatility could be associated to the

nature of the several stabilization plans adopted in those countries. and to changes in the

exchange rate regimes.

This paper is organized as follows. The next section presents the model. Section 3

contains the empirical results. Section 4 concludes and points directions for future

research.

I Some authors argue that a conditional variance measure is preferred because it captures better the notion of uncertainry in the theoretical modelo since a variable can be very \'olatile but in a known (thus. certain)

fashion. See. for example. Caporale and Doroodian (1994).

(7)

2. The Model

In a simple general equilibrium framework. the model presented here tries to

capture the effect of the volatility of the real exchange rate on its equilibrium leveI. The

effect arises from the assumption that firms are risk averse and the decision on how much

to export is made before the real exchange rate is observed. When the export activity is

riskier relative to the others. less resources \Vill be allocated to it. To maintain externaI

balance. the real exchange rate has to be more depreciated. Therefore. there is a negative

relation between the equilibrium real exchange rate and its volatility.

ProdUClion

A small open economy is considered. which produces three goods: a non-tradable

good ( QN)' an importable good ( Q\f) and an exported good ( Qx). The importable good is

a substitute of the country' s imports. The exported good is that good produced

exclusively for export. and is not consumed locally. It can be thought as a good that is

produced to attend foreign specifications. It is assumed that at the beginning of the

period. before obsen'ing the realization or the real exchange rate. firms have to make a

binding contract speci(ving the amount to be produced of the exported good. Assuming

that the producer is risk averse. he \ViII maximize the expected \'alue or a concave

function. which \vill be called utility fllnction. of his profit. The problem of a

representative firm at the beginning of the period is represented by:

( 1 )

For simplicity. only one mobile factor of production exists. L. presenting

decreasing returns. and the tirm' s endO\vment o f this factor is [. Q \ ( L'( ). Q \/ ( LI/ ). and QvC[ - L'( - LI/) represent the production fllnctions of the exported. importable and

(8)

non-tradable goods. respectively. The relative prices or the exported and importable

goods in terms of the non-tradable good.

i

jx and

p\"

are uncertain. The price of the

exported good is equal to its international price. p~. exogenous and assumed constant. • multiplied by the ratio bet\veen the nominal exchange rate and the price of the

non-tradable good. This ratio. represented by

R.

is uncertain. and the cause of this uncertainty will be discussed later. The price of the importable good is equal to its international price .

p,~, multiplied by the sum ofthe uncertain ratio

R

and the import tariff r.

Px

=

RP:"

and

Plf

= (

R

+

r)

P

~f

.

(2)

By solving the maximization problem above. the producer chooses how much

labor to allocate for the production of the exported good2. The two first order conditions that define L'( and Llf are:

E[U'

Px]

=

Q,.,:' •

and

E[U]

Q/

(3.a)

E[U'

PII]

= Qv'

E[

U'] Q,1f' (3.b)

where U' is the derivative of the utility function with respect to protits. and

QJ'

IS the

marginal product or labor in the production or goodj. forj=.L\f.S.

Gi\'en the properties or the production functions. the production of the exported

good is positively related to E[ U

Px] -

which can be interpreted as the marginal utility for the producer or producing one extra unit of the exported good - and is negatively

related to E( U) - which can be interpreted as the marginal utility for the producer of

:2 The solution also yields the amount planned to be allocated to the importable and to the non-tradable

goods, However. the decision or ho\\ much labor is allocated between them is made after the realization or

the real exchange rate.

(9)

producing one extra unit of the non-tradable good. The amount of exported good to be

produced can then be represented by:

Qx =

Cfx( E(U Px)' E( U p\!). E( U))

(4) The derivative of the offer curve with respect to the first argument is positive, and with

respect to the other two it is negative.

After the realization of the real exchange rate, the firm decides how much to

produce of the importable and non-tradable goods with the labor net of the amount used

in the production of the exported good. The offer function of the two goods are

represented as the functions:

Q\I

=

Cf

\1

(VII'

E (U Px ), E

(U'

p\! ), E (

U' )) and

Qv

=

Cf.v(PM,E(U' Px),E(U' p.\I),E(U')).

(5.a)

(5.b)

where VII is the realization of the variable

PM'

The derivatives of the two functions have the following signs:

dqM

> O,

dqM

>0.

dqM

< O.

dq.v

< O.

dqN

<O.

dp.\f

dE[U PM]

. dE[U]

dPM

dE[U PM]

dqN

> O. and

dE[U]

Consumplion

dq,

O t' '- LI I\T [ ] < orJ-;Vl.H.

dE

U' -Px

~ ow that the production side of the economy is defined. ler' s turn to the consumption decisions. The consumer in this model economy consumes two types of

goods: importables and non-tradables. They maximize their utility from consumption.

subject to their budget constraint. 1 t is also assumed that their demand for goods depends

positively on the amount of money they hold. Two possible ways to model this

assumption are either by using a cash-in-advance constraint. or by placing money in the

utility function. The role of introducing money is this model is to create a demand shock.

Hence. money should be viewed here solely as a source of demand shocks. An alternative

(10)

instance. that would have a positive effect on the demand

01'

both goods. The demand for each type of good may be represented by:

Clt

=

c" ( fJ" ,111) and

C" =

c,,( p",m).

(6.a) (6.b)

where m is the real amount of money in terms

01'

the price

01'

the non-tradable good. and

de

\I

de"

d

de

J f i ' .

- ' - <

O. - -> O. an - > O or}=A1.lv.

dPM

dPI1

dm

Equilibrium Conditions

There are two equilibrium conditions in this economy. The first one is that the total production of the non-tradable good must equal its total consumption. The condition is represented by the following equation:

( 7)

The second condition is that the countr/ s trade balance constraint must also be satisfied. Assuming that there are no transactions with the rest of the world other than trade relations. this constraint translates into a balanced trade equation:

P~I

[ cII ( VII' III ) - q AI ( VII' E (U' jj x ), E

([j'

PI/)' E ( U' ) ) ]

=

= p~,qx( E( U' Px). E(U' P\I)' E( U'))

(8)

Ex-post relative price or importables and real money supply must satisf\ the two equilibrium equations above. gi\'en the distribution function ofthe random variables. The equilibrium is represented in figure I, The vertical axis depicts the relative price of importables. and the horizontal axis represents the real money supply, The equilibrium occurs \vhere the non-tradables market equilibrium curve (NT). that represents equation (7). crosses the trade balance curve (TB). that represents equation (8),

8

C

r

(11)

pM

m

Figure 1

Uneertainty is introdueed in the model through the money supply. Ali eeonomie

agents know the distribution for the possible realization 01' the money supply. and the govemment sets the nominal exehange rate without observing its realizatÍon. The rigidity

of the nominal exehange rate is what makes the variability of the money supply to have

real effeets. 0Iominal exehange rate is set by the governrnent targeting the equilibrium real

exchange rate. However. priees are eollected with a lag. Therefore. in an inflationary

environment. priees may be different from expeeted. and the real exehange rate may result

misaligned. The setting modeled here represents sue h a situation. Henee. the real exchange

rate will be different from the equilibrium one when the rate 01' int1ation. or. in the eontext of our static model. \vhen the money supply is different from expeeted. This means that

the \'ariability of the real exehange rate will be larger the larger is the variability of the

int1ation rate. or the larger the variability of the money supply in our model.

Soh'ing lhe .\lodef

Equilibrium in the model is achieved as follows. The govemment sets the nominal

(12)

expected value. and zero import tariffs. In terms of figure 1. nominal exchange rate is set

so that VI! equals its equilibrium value. with zero tariffs. \Vhen the realization of the

money supply is larger than expected. the demand for both goods is also larger than

expected. and the economy is at a point to the right of the equilibrium point. To

reestablish equilibrium in both markets, the price 01' non-tradables increases. ando at the same time. we assume that an import tariff is levied. so that real money supply retums to

its (expected) equilibrium leveI. while the relative price of importables remains unchanged.

On the other hand. when the realized nominal money supply is smaller than its expected

value. the price of non-tradables decreases while an import subsidy is put in effect. Given

that the value of the tariff will be greater than zero at realizations of the money supply

larger than its mean. and it is symmetrically negative on the opposite case. then the

expected value of tariffs is zero].

The relative price of importables will then be the same for any realization of the

money supply. The same is not true for the relative price of the exported good. When the

money supply is larger than expected. for instance. the relative price of the exported good

is smaller than expected. Therefore. the variability of the relative price of the exported

good is positively related to the variability of the money supply. which represents here

the \"ariabilitv 01' the int1ation rate.

The equations that determine the production decision for the exported good (2.a)

and the plan for the production 01' other goods (2.b) can then be rewritten as:

3 Note that the role 01' the tariff in the model is just to maintain externai balance \\hen the realization of the random variable is different from expected. This could also be accomplished by aliowing the country to run deticits or surpluses. using the international financiai market. We want. ho\\ever. to keep a static framework for simplicity"

10 818UOTECA

M.~RIO

HENR:aUE

SIMONSE~

(13)

E[U'

í\,]

=

Q\'. and

E[U]

Qx' Q\' VII

=

Q "

,lI (3.a') (3.b')

To assess the effect of changes in the variability of inflation on the equilibrium

inflation rate. one has to determine the effect of that variability on the expected values

above. and that. in turno depends on the concavity of the functions U'

Px

and U' with respect to

Px.

Concavity of the first function and convexity

01'

the second-l are sufficient conditions for the variability of

Px

to affect negatively the production of the exported good. and positively the production of importables. It is plausible to assume this sign for

the derivatives. so thm when the expected vaI ue oi' the marginal utility oi' one more unit of

production 01' exported good (

E[ U

Px])

decreases due to a higher \'olatility of

Px'

for instance. the tirm will lower the production 01' exported good, and will increase the production of importables and non-tradables.

Finally. the equilibrium conditions can nO\\' be re\VTitten as:

C.v(P,11

,li!)

=

q,,(

V\f' E( U' jJx )' E( U'))

p;, [

cII (VII' /Jl) - (I II ( fi 11' E( U' jJ \' ). E( U' ))] =

= p~ q x ( P,w E ( U' jJ \ ). E ( U' ) )

( 7')

( 8')

:-low \ve are ready to shO\\' that the \'ariability 01' the real exchange rate. which wiU be shown to depend positively on the variability 01' the intlation rate. affects positively the equilibrium real exchange rate.

The real exchange rate is the ratio 01' the price of tradables and the price 01' non-tradables. In terms 01' the model presented here. the real exchange rate is:

RER

=

n(

T>\f" i\).

( 9)

-l The function L" /!, can be concave and C' convex in 17, at the same time. because

c{ L" (i,

=

L" " /) \ ( Q,

r

+ 2 L" , Q, < C' , , ( Q,

r

=

rJ_: I " ,

(14)

where the derivative 01' the function D(.) is positive with respect to both arguments. First. it is clear that the \'ariability 01' the real exchange rate depends positively on the variability 01' the rei ative prices of importable and exported goods. \vhich \·ariability. in turno increases with the variability of inflation.

Remember that:

Px

= Rp'~, and

P

M = (

R

+

T)

P

~I

.

(2)

Hence. to determine the effect of the \'ariability on the equilibrium real exchange

rate we must determine its etTect on T and

R.

The \'alue of the tariff wil! always be such as to keep the relative price 01' importables unchanged. To determine the effect on

R

we need to know the etTect of real exchange rate variability on the equilibrium value p\P and

on the possible realizations 01'

Px'

Figure 2 represents the changes in the equilibrium conditions caused by an increase

in the variability of

Px'

From the assumptions in equations (2'). \vhen the variability of

Px

increases. the production of non-tradables also increases. Thus. the curve NT in figure

:2 shifts up\vard and to the right relative to its previous position.

The effect on the country's trade balance constraint is ambiguous. The increased

\'ariability 01' jJx decreases production of exported good. but at the same time it increases production 01' importables. It is plausible to assume. hO\vever. that the tirst etTect is larger than the second. so that the TB curve shifts upward and to the left.

(15)

pM TB'

m

Figure 2

It is clear from the picture that the ne\\' equilibrium value for the price of imports

is larger than before. and therefore so is the expected value of

Px'

Consequently. the equilibrium real exchange rate is larger the larger its variability. The intuition for this result

is that the increase in variability of the RER depresses exports. so that to maintain

externaI balance an incentive in the form of a RER depreciation is necessary.

The model shows that the volatility of the inflation rate has a positive effect on

the volatility 01' the RER. and the volatility 01' the RER. in turno affects positively the cquilibrium real exchange rate.

3. Real Exchange Rate Volatility

There is a vast empirical literature on the effects of (nominal and real) exchange

rate variability on trade t1O\vs and trade prices.=' Most 01' the papers in this literature \Vere based on partial equilibrium models of export determination. In general. the main sources

" For a good survey on the most recent empirical literature on exchange rate \olatility and trade. see Côté

(1994). Among other important contributions. see Gotur ( 1985). Kenen and Rodrik ( 1986). Caballero and

(16)

of exchange rate \·olatility considered \Vere associated to the end of the Bretton \Voods

system or issues related to the introduction or economic integration regions (Nafta.

European Union. and 0.1ercosul). like macroeconomic policy harmonization and currency

umons.

The results regarding the effects of exchange rate volatility on trade flows are still

inconclusive. While most papers found a negative significant effect . the magnitudes of the

coefficients are in general relatively small. For evidence of a negative relationship between

real exchange rate (RER) volatility and trade in developing countries. see Coes (1979).

Paredes (1989). and Grobar (1993). For e\·idence of no relationship between the two

variables in Colombia. see Steiner and Wullner ( 1994).

On the other hand. most authors tend to tind an increase in exchange rate volatility

after the collapse or the Bretton Woods regime. most notably in developing countries (see

Edwards. 1989). Reaional economic intearation was also 1'ound to reduce the effect 01' ~ ~

exchange rate variability on trade (see. for example. Frankel and Wei. 1993).

In this paper. we depart 1'rom the previous empirical literature in two ways.

The first innovation is to investigate a different source of RER volatility: the

effects of stabilization plans in high inflation countries. As our model suggests. for a given

exchange rate indexation regime. int1ation variability and RER variability are positively

correlated. Changes in the indexation regime or changes from a tixed to a t10ating exchange

rate system are also other potential sources of RER variability. By examining the behavior

of volatility indexes over the last ten to tifteen years for Brazil. Argentina and Mexico. we

try to identity the int1uence 01' stabilization plans on these variability measures.

(17)

The second inno\'ation here is the use of daily data for Brazil. By assuming a

constant exponential growth for prices within each month. \ve were able to obtain daill'

RERs since Januar; 1,1 of 1980 for Brazil.(,

Graphs 1 and:2 displal' daill' Brazilian RER leveIs and changes. respectivell'. from

the beginning of 1980 to the end of June 1995. Daily nominal exchange rates (E) were

obtained from the Central Bank: sell quotation. dollar/domestic currencl'. As usual in

small economy models. real exchange rates \Vere proxied bl' RER =

E*WP(ICPI.

where Wp( is the U.S. wholesale price index and CPI is the Brazilian consumer price index

(lNPC. also from IBGE).7

A very volatile RER picture emerges from the graphs. Large one-dal' swings were

observed in the 30% maxi-devaluation episode 01' February 1983. and in several mid-devaluations that preceded most stabilization plans of the 1980s. Months of steep

inflation accelerationldeceleration not onll' brought changes in the RER leveI but also

caused an increase in (within-month) volatility. which is not perceived in monthll' data.

We use the (moving) standard deviation of daily RER changes as our measure of

volatility. We computed tour \'ersions 01' this measure: two using the standard deviation of the RER changes \vithin each quarter (STD-Q). and two within each semester (STD-S).

The difference bet\\'een the members 01' each pair is that one 01' them is centered in the middle 01' each quarter (or semester). while in the other each standard deviation date corresponded to the last observation of each quarter (or semester). We use a C at the end

of the names of the centered measures.

I, The :1ssumption of:1 const:1nt exponenti:11 price growth \\ithin e:1ch month does not seem d:1maging to

our results. since eX-:1nte RER expect:1tions should be based on a hypothesis like this. :15 other distributions :1re unkno\\n,

See Edw:1rds (1989) for :1 comp:1rison 01' sever:11 llle:1sures 01' RERs, The S:1llle definition 01' RER was :1pplied to Argentina and Mexico.

(18)

Table 1 shows the means of the four measures of RER volatility. together with the

dai!v int1ation averaae. Remember that these averaaes are taken over weekdavs onlv . , . . . ... .. .. ..

excludina weekends. holidavs. and bank holidavs. The maanitudes were re!ativelv hiah ... .. . , . . . .. ... (around 0.7% a working day), about the same size as the daily rate of inflation. T able 1

also shows the correlation between our four measures and with inflation. Contrary to

other studies for other countries, the four measures are not very highly correlated with

each other. Moreover. all measures were found to be uncorrelated with the inflation rate.

As our model suggests. it is the variability of inflation (not the leveI) that matters for

explaining RER volatility. Changes in the exchange rate indexation regime are also

important in this respect.

Graph 3 shows the behavior of our preferred volatility measure (STD-QC).

Several comments emerge from that graph. First of alI. most peaks in the volatility

measure were related to large devaluations. that were made either to deal with the externaI

debt crisis. as in February of 1983. or preceding stabilization plans.8 The remaining peaks

ret1ected large appreciations that followed both the Collor and the Real plans.

Second. if we do not consider those peaks. at least six volatility patterns can be

identified. The first one. observed in the period running from 1980 to February 1983. is

characterized by a relatively high volatility (around 0.7% a day). which resulted from a

loose cra\vling peg regime without a fixed-period indexation rule. The second period.

observed from February-1983 to mid-1985. was one of a daily indexation. However.

int1ation acceleration (from 100% a year to 200% a year) compensated the indexation

effect. resulting in a RER volatility of around 0.7% a month. similar to that observed in

the first period. The third period. from mid-1985 to the end of 1988. was characterized

XWe stress the point that these peaks should be kept as part of lhe volatility indexo since in ali lhese

periods. for"ard-Iaaking agenls "ere uncertain about lhe future leveis af lhe RER. anticipaling the possibility af large devaluations or price freezing.

(19)

by a Im\' daily RER \'olatility (around 0.2% a day). which resulted from two price (and

exchange rate) freezing attempts and a policy orientation of keeping the RER unchanged.

despi te the intlation acceleration at the end of the period. The fourth period runs from

1990 to the middle of 1991. period in \vhich the Central Bank did not follow any

indexation (parity) rule. letting the exchange rate tloat under unspecified thresholds. \vhich

characterized what is usually called a "dirty tloating" regime. The result was a ver)' high

RER voiatility (above 1 % a day). A fifth period. from mid-1991 to mid-1994. illustrates

the retum to a daiiy indexation regime and was characterized by some attempts to point

to a more devaiued currency. Continuous inflation acceleration in that period. together

with a lag on current price observation. resulted in a continuous increase in the volatility

measure. The magnitudes. however. were not large. compared to other periods. averaging

around 0.3% a day, The sixth pattem was the one introduced by the floating exchange

regime that followed the Real Plano After a brief period of a reiativeiy high volatility.

which was caused by the large appreciation of the Real. inflation stabilization at low

leveis. together with the introduction of exchange rate bands in March 1995 helped to

decrease the RER variability. However. RER volatility is stilllarger than the one observed

in the fourth period. period in which the average int1ation rate was around 25% a month.

Graphs 4. 5 and 6 show RER monthly changes for Argentina. Mexico and Brazil.

respectively. [Comments to come]

We computed three measures of \'olatility for each countr:' s monthly data. ali

based on (moving) standard deviations of RER changes: one for changes within the last 12

months (STD-12): another for changes within the last 24 months (STD-24): and a third

centered in the middle of each year (STD-12C), Table :2 shows the means of the three

volatility measures for the three countries. respecti\'ely, i t also gives the correlation

matrix between the three measures and the int1ation rate. Mexico experienced the lowest

average levei of int1ation (3.5% a month) and the lowest RER volatility measures. in

(20)

int1ation (3.5% a month) and the highest RER \'olatility measures. both in absolute terms

and relative to the int1ation rate. Note that Brazil" s monthly volatility index is much lower

than its daily counterpan analyzed above (.3.2% a month compared to around 12~/o. the monthly equivalent

01'

the daily measure).

Graph 7 displays the centered (moving) yearly standard deviation

01'

the RER (STD-12C). We ignored the large 1989-1991 numbers for Argentina which were above

60% a month. so as to provide a better visual comparison between the three countries.

Mexico experienced the lowest RER volatility among the three countries. specially after

the events of late 1982. It remained below 2% a month throughout most 01' the period. A.rgentina· s RER \'olatility was the highest 01' the group. After 1991. however. RER volatility remained below 0.5% a month. the lowest leveI reached by any 01' the three countries in the period.

[To be completed]

~. Future Research

As our theoretical model showed. RER volatility seems to affect positively the

~quilibrium real exchange rate leveI. We intend to test empirically this result by estimating the equilibrium RER. :\. traditional method 01' estimating equilibrium RER has been applied to other developing countries' data by Edwards (1995) and Elbadawi (1995).

among others. usual!y using real variables such as terms 01' trade and fiscal and monetary \'ariables as the long-run determinants 01' the RER. In a future paper. we intend to apply this method to Brazil. including RER volatility as one of the variables that cointegrate

\vith the RER.

In future research. \\'e also intend to estimate conditional variances. We wil! try to

invest in techniques for detecting the problems associated with the presence of structural

breaks mentioned in the introduction. Contrary to other applications. we will study the

possibility 01' using a \cctor error correction model \vith the error correction given by the

(21)

equilibrium RER equation as mentioned above. since most GARCH models are clearly

inadequate for picking up effects such as expectations of large exchange rate devaluations

following a balance of payments crisis. for example. In fac!. most GARCH applications

use ARlMA specifications for the RER equation. which obviously do not carry enough

(22)

Bibliography

CabaIlero. Ricardo and Vittorio Corbo (1989), "The Effect of Real Exchange Rate Uncertainty on Exports: Empirical Evidence", The World Bank Ecnomic Review.

vo1. 3. n. 2.

Caporale. Tony and Khosrow Doroodian (1994). "Exchange Rate Variability and the FIow of InternationaI Trade". Economic Lelters 46.

Coes (1979), .,.

Côté. Agathe (1994). "Exchange Rate VoIatility and Trade: A Survey", Working Paper 94-5. Bank of Canada.

Cushman. David (1983). "The Effects of Real Exchange Risk on International Trade".

Jaumal oflnternational Economics 15. August.

De Grauwe. Paul (1988). "Exchange Rate Variabilitv and the Slowdown in Gro\vth of

~

-International Trade"". International .\Jonela,.y FllJ1d Slai! Papers 35. March.

Edwards. Sebastian ( 1989). Real Exchange Rales. Del'aluation. and Adjuslment: Exchanf{e Rale Pa/icy in Del'eloping Countries. The !\1IT Press.

Ed\vards. Sebastian ( 1994). "Real and Monetary Determinants of Real Exchange Rate Behavior: Theory ~md Evidence from Developing Countries". in Estimalúlg Eq/lilihrilll71 Real Exchange Rales. John Williamson (ed.). Institute for

Intemational Economics, Washington, De.

EIbadawi, lbrahim ( 1994). "Estimating Long Run Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate". in

ESlil71ating Equilihriul71 Real Exchange Rules. John Williamson (ed.). Institute for

I ntemational Economics. Washington, De.

Frankel. J. and \Vei. S-J. ( 1993 L "Trade Blocs and Currency Blocs'·. mimeo.

Gagnon. Joseph (1993). "Exchange Rate Variability and Foreign Trade in the Presence

01'

Adjustment costs·' . .!oztrlwl o/Il1lenwlional Ecol1ol71ics ]4.

(23)

Glicko Reuveno Peter Kretzmer and Clas Wihlborg (1995)0 "Real Exchange Rate Effects of Monetary Disturbances under Different Degrees of Exchange Rate Flexibility: An Empirical Analysis"o Joumal oflntemalional Economics 380

Goturo Padma (1985), 00 Effects of Exchange Rate Volatility on Trade: Some Further Evidence"o International Monetary Fund StajfPapers 320

Grobar. Lisa (1993). ooThe Effect of Real Exchange Rate Uncertainty on LDC Manufactured Exports"o Journal of Development Economics 410

Paredes (1989). 0 0 o

Steiner. Ro and Wullner. Ao ( 1994). "Efecto de la Volatilidad de la Tasa de Cambio en las Exportaciones No Tradicionales"o Coyztntura Economica. December.

(24)

TA B LE 1

Brazil: Oaily RER Volatility Measures MEANS

STO-Q STO-S STO-QC STO-SC INFL

0,66 0,73

I

0,66

I

0,72

I

0,69

CORRELATION MATRIX

STO-Q STO-S S TO-QC STO-SC INFL

STO-Q 1,00 0,77 0,58 0,73 -0,04 STO-S 0,77 1,00 0,48 0,58 -0,08 STO-QC 0,58 0,48 1,00 0,76 0,12 STO-SC 0,73 0,58 0,76 1,00 0,09 INFL -0,04

I

-0,08

I

0,12

I

0,09 1,00 Table 2

Real Exchange Rate Volatilities: Means

ST012 ST024 ST012C INFL

Brazil 3,02 3,35 3,02 15,39

Argentina 9,27 11,97 9,27 12,69

(25)

2.2

2

1.8

1.6

Real Exchange Rate -

Br~zil

Daily - Reais of 15/6/95

W./~'lf

f~./IJ·

fi '/1 '. I I

" I

, ) '\ :

\J\(

1')\

1 4 I:::·\,

• / ' .

\

I : \1 . '\ \ ... "'\, /''1'1' \ ' ,

1 2

\

i",,,,'" '-.ti \ " i \' I' J\ '" ) • \' \ tAl

,,j

\ ' 1 ' , , , :' \ I Y , \.(1/ ')~' ~ ,j

I \" '

~t· , '; \

1

\

'li:

~ fV-\~

.\!~

:

\

\",

,t,'1r

~

\,

' . \

0.8

I

1 ; ' 1 .

I

Dec-79 Apr-81 Sep-82 Jan-84 Jun-85 Oct-86 Feb-88 Jul-89 Nov-90 Apr-92 Aug-93 Jan-95

GJ

~

tU

:r: f-'

(26)

20

15

10

5

11 '," !II

O

IL:l!lilliliili~)miclt:tii.

Real Exchange Rate - Brazil

Daily Variation

(%)

I

!

:I!~i:

! I 1' '" I

'I

/:'

I I I ,I , '~i I " , : ' ,: I I , ' I , ,: , , ' I ' " I ' : /1 I : ' i' il ' :: il I" ,11' I' '

.'A')J,,~)

I~

)11

0 ),:;

,~I~,:

i ,

:t+-ii+'11hln'lMM,

" I

~~I

' , '

'

I:

' j '

!

-5

I

Dee-79 Apr-81 Sep-82 Jan-84 Jun-85 Oet-86 Feb-88 Jul-89 Nov-90 Apr-92 Aug-93 Jan-95

GJ

S;

'TI

::r:: "V

(27)

4

3

2

1

Volatility: Daily RER Changes - Brazil

Std Deviation - Quarter, Centered

(%)

i ! I I ,

ll\

I

".' f 1 I1 \

/

/\~

f

~1',c,jC"{'

""' .... '

,~_/{

•• '\J' \.: I,," \\ ,

!

~

I

i I \

,J

I

t

IV \

I

\\j

\ ,

i

\

IJ rl'IJI{J V

O

I I,co, t \-

IJ11

j t

..

f ( 1 , j I

t1 (

j - t ti f I t

Dec-79 Apr-81 Sep-82 Jan-84 Jun-85 Oct-86 Feb-88 Jul-89 Nov-90 Apr-92 Aug-93 Jan-95

GJ 'lj >' 'lj ::r: w

(28)

50

40

30

20

10

O

-10

Real Exchange Rate - Argentina

Monthly Changes

(0/0)

f

I'"

'.1'

11

1

,11

11

1"

'·'111, ...

.11.11'111111"11" .

'Ir·

.,II{ ... IIIIIIIIII"lllllr

'11111' 111"11'11'1"

'I""U' ... ' ... ', ... ..

-2 O

111111111111111111

i

11111111111111 i 1111111

i

11 i 11111111111 j j 11111 11 11111 H 111 H I j

li

j

~

11111

~I ~

111111111111111111 j 1111 11 11111111 j 11 j 11 11 11111111 11 11 11 11 111111

Aug-82

Aug-84

Aug-86

Aug-88

Aug-90

Aug-92

Aug-94

Aug-83

Aug-85

Aug-87

Aug-89

Aug-91

Aug-93

GJ

~

'tJ

:r::

(29)

15

10

5

o

-5

Real Exchange Rate - Mexico

Monthly Changes

(010)

..

-1 O

I111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111I11111II1111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111I1111II1IIIIII111I111IIIIIIII1I1I1

Oct-82 Oct-84 Oct-86 Oct-88 Oct-90 Oct-92

Oct-83 Oct-85 Oct-87 Oct-89 Oct-91 Oct-93

GJ

~

l-cJ

::r: lJ1

(30)

20

i

15

10

5

I

Real Exchange Rate - Brazil

Monthly

Ch~nges

(Ofc»

,.

o

/IIIII·'IIII,hl'".I",

r

'11',1/1

1

,111111

).)llllr,.llllf'wlll'llIrllllll~llJI'll

'1

1/" ,,

1

1

111

.1.1

1,

Ir'

.,1'1'1'"

1

11

11

1

1'-1'

1111'

i"

I"

1 I

-5

-10

-1

~

/111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111 /1111111111/111/111 1111/11111111111111/111111111111111 II/IIIH/II 1I/1I/1I1I//IIIIIIIIIIIIHIHlllltllIllIlIllIlIllIlIlIlI/IIIIIIIIII/1I 1 11111

'"teb-80 Feb-82 Feb-84 Feb-86 Feb-88 Feb-90 Feb-92 Feb-94

Feb-81 Feb-83 Feb-85 Feb-87 Feb-89 Feb-91 Feb-93 Feb-95

GJ

~

~

::r::

(31)

,"

12

10

8

6

4

2

,

Volatility: Monthly RER Changes

Std Deviation - 12 Months Centered

(0/0)

1

f\J\..!:

,\

.

'I I I ,

,

,

\

,

!\\-j

, , , , , "

,

-<

, I

I

\

,

,

,

,

L - - ,

o

lillllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllilllllllllllllll11111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111I11111111111111111111111111 Jan-82 Apr-83 Jul-84 Oct-85 Jan-87 Apr-88 Jul-89 Oct-90 Jan-92 Apr-93 Jul-94

ARGENT. -

BRAZIL

MEXICO

I

GJ

~

tU

::r:

(32)

.<~[70'~

.~~V'

t/'

:~~

-s:';-"

li

I BIBLIOTECA

t,~

MAlHO HENRIOUE SIMONSEN .:

:"i.Cham. P/EPGE SPE T323s

Autor: Terra. Maria CristIna T.

Título: Stabilization, volatdity and the equdibnulll real e

IIIIIII

~IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII

CC;\ - BMHS

000087379 I/ "11/11/11/111/11111/11111/1" 111/1

Referências

Documentos relacionados

Methods: One hundred and eight patients with rhizarthritis and multiple arthritis (191 hands with clinical and radiographic rhi- zarthritis) followed for two years as part of

Considerando o objectivo de contribuir para uma melhor gestão do espaço público com base nas tecnologias SIG, neste trabalho estudam-se as temáticas das frentes de água e

concebida no intuito de apresentar aos países um mandamento a ser seguido; claro que, hoje, essa ideia foi superada, reconhecendo o respeito à dignidade humana nos mais

Principal matéria prima utilizada na fabricação do produto é a madeira com combinação de diferentes materiais nos móveis fabricados, sendo madeira (angelim,

Os debates foram moderados por Miguel de Castro Neto, Subdiretor da NOVA IMS – Information Management School e Coordenador da NOVA Cidade – Urban Analytics Lab, e tiveram

Neste caso ha uma fractura dupla vertical ; se o choque incide sobre os dois ischions, o traço da fractura passa pela linha dos buracos sagrados, de cada lado, e o sacro que

The probability of attending school four our group of interest in this region increased by 6.5 percentage points after the expansion of the Bolsa Família program in 2007 and

Finally, for the case of the budget balance and real GDP growth (bid ask spread, debt-to-GDP ratio, real effect exchange rate and VIX), the larger (higher) in absolute value