• Nenhum resultado encontrado

Inflation forecasts' performance in Latin America

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Inflation forecasts' performance in Latin America"

Copied!
12
0
0

Texto

(1)

ScienceDirect

ReviewofDevelopmentFinance7(2017)157–168

Full

length

article

Inflation

Forecasts’

Performance

in

Latin

America

João

Tovar

Jalles

a,b,

aCentreforGlobalizationandGovernance,NovaSchoolofBusinessandEconomics,CampusCampolide,Lisbon1099-032,Portugal bUECEResearchUnitonComplexityandEconomics,TechnicalUniversityofLisbon,Portugal

Availableonline10October2017

Abstract

ThispaperprovidesafullcharacterizationofinflationrateforecastsusingthemeanvaluesfromConsensusEconomicsforasampleof14 LatinAmericancountriesbetween1989and2014.Italsoassessestheperformanceofinflationrateforecastsaroundbusinesscycles’turning points.Resultsshowthatinflationforecastsintheregiondisplaythestandardpropertythatastheforecasthorizonshortensaccuracyimproves. Onaverage,forecastersunderpredictinflation,butthismasksverydifferentcountryexperiences.Wefindevidencepointtobiasednessofinflation forecastsforyear-aheadforecastsbutnotforcurrentyear.Tests’resultspointtoforecastinefficiencywhichisalsoevidencedbyatendencyto smooththembetweenrevisions.Focusingonbusinesscycleturningpoints,forecasterstendtoslightlyunderpredicttheinflationrateandthe extentofunderpredictionincreasesduringrecessions.Thehypothesisofforecastefficiencyisoverwhelminglyrejectedbothduringrecessionsand recoveries.

© 2017 Africagrowth Institute. Production and hosting by Elsevier B.V.This is an open access article underthe CC BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).

JELclassifications: C53;E27;E37;E62;D8

Keywords:Forecastcomparison;Bias;Efficiency;Informationrigidity;Recession;Recovery

1. Introduction

LatinAmericahasbeenknownforitsdisplayofhighinflation

ratesandevenepisodes of hyperinflation,particularlyshortly

afteritspoliticaltransitiontodemocracyinthe1980sandearly

1990s.1Morerecently,theimportantcurrencydepreciationsthat

affectedmanyLatinAmericancountrieshaveplacedrenewed

upwardpressureoninflation,eveniftheirimpacthasbeenmilder

thaninthepast.2Vigilanceisinanycasewarrantedineconomies

wheresecond-roundeffects are potentially big,sincethereis

quietvariabilityastohowwell-anchoredinflationexpectations

areindifferentcountries.Thisisimportantsinceseveralpapers

Theusualdisclaimerapplies.Allremaining errorsaretheauthor’ssole responsibility.

Correspondenceto:CentreforGlobalizationandGovernance,NovaSchool ofBusinessandEconomics,CampusCampolide,Lisbon1099-032,Portugal.

E-mailaddress:joaojalles@gmail.com

1 ForseminalworksoninflationinLatinAmericarefertothestudiesbyBaer

(1967)andCole(1987).

2 Notethatimprovementsinmonetaryframeworksoverthepasttwodecades haveledtosubstantialandgeneralizeddeclinesinexchangeratepass-through toconsumerprices.

typicallypointtothenegativeeffectsofinflationoneconomic

growth.3

Theseverityandpersistenceofthefallinoutputduringthe

GlobalFinancialCrisis(GFC)ledtosignificantdeclinesin

infla-tionratesaroundtheworld.Sincethen,inflationonaveragehas

increasedandsomecentralbanksintheLatinAmericanregion

currentlyfaceatrade-off.On theonehand,domesticdemand

isweak,withsomeuncertaintyaroundoutputgaps,andfiscal

policyspaceislimitedornonexistent.Ontheotherhand,

head-line inflationisabovetargetandexpectedtoremain sointhe

nearterm.4 Such conjuncturetriggeredarevival of the

inter-estinunderstandingthe deepcauses,costsandconsequences

3 Forinstance,Fisher(1993)presentedsomeinternationalcross-sectionaland paneldataevidencetosuggestthatinflationoutweighedtheMundell–Tobin effect.Barro(1995)makinguseofcross-sectionalanalysis,suggestedthatthe high-inflationcountriesinhissampledrovethenegativeeffectsofinflationon outputgrowth.DeGregorio(1993)providedsomeearlyevidenceusingapanel oftwelveLatinAmericancountriesduringthe1950–1985period,andsuggested thatinflationwasindeeddetrimentaltoeconomicgrowth.

4 Forarecentsurveyontheregion’seconomicoutlookseeIMF(2016a).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rdf.2017.09.002

1879-9337/© 2017 Africagrowth Institute. Production and hosting by Elsevier B.V. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).

(2)

ofinflationdynamics.5 Understandinginflationdynamicsisa

very important as well as a timely and timeless issue.

Fore-castingitcorrectly,however,seemsanequallyimportantissue

butit hasreceivedfar lessprominence. Giventhe well

docu-mentedrelationshipbetweencyclicalfeatures ofinflationand

unemployment(PhillipsCurve)andhowstructuralpoliciescan

affectaggregatedemand(IMF,2016b)andimprovelabor

mar-ketmatching(Bovaetal.,2016),itisimportanttoassesshow

forecastershavebeenperformingwhenitcomestopredicting

inflation.Recentstudieshavealsodocumentedhowinflationrate

(professional)forecastsareconsistentwiththePhillipsCurve.6

Suchliteraturecan beviewedinthe broaderscopeof testing

whethermacroeconomicempiricalregularitiesholdtruewhen

usingforecastsinsteadofactualdata.7

Inthiscontext,andacknowledgingtherelevanceofbusiness

cycle behavior to inflation dynamics (Tatom, 1978; Oinonen

etal.,2013),thispaperaimstoassesstheperformanceof

infla-tionforecastsinasampleofLatinAmericancountriesinboth

normal times but also around business cycle turning points.

Recentforecastingassessmentexercisesaroundbusinesscycles

turningpointsforeithertheGDPgrowthorthebudget

balance-to-GDP-ratioforacross-sectionofcountriesusingConsensus

EconomicsdatawerecarriedoutbyLounganietal.(2013)and

Jallesetal.(2015),respectively.However,aperusalofthe

lit-erature findsnosuch analysis forthe caseof inflationinthis

particularregionoftheworld.Tothisend,werelyontheprivate

sector’spredictionsfortheinflationrateforasampleof14Latin

American economies between October 1989 and September

2014 brought together by Consensus Economics—which are

knowntobehardtobeat(BatchelorandDua,1992).8

The paper proposes toaddress the following, more

expo-sitional,questions:(i) Howdo inflationforecasts behaveand

performstatistically?(ii)Whatsensitivityanalysiscanbemade

atdifferentforecasthorizons,thatis,isthereamarked

differ-encebetweencurrent-yearandyear-aheadpredictions?(iii)Do

forecasters,onaverage,under-orover-predicttheinflationrate

andfor how long?iv) Are inflationforecastsaccurate during

recessionsandrecoveriesepisodes?Toanswerthesequestions,

5 See the remarks of the ECB Vice-President Mr Constancio about “Understanding Inflation Dynamics and Monetary Pol-icy in a Low Inflation Environment” (5 November 2015) —

https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/date/2015/html/sp1511051.en.html. 6 Forinstance,Fendeletal.(2011)provideevidenceonthetrustof profes-sionalforecastersinalternativeexpectationalversionsofthePhillipscurvefor agroupof7advancedeconomies.Rülke(2012)assesseswhetherprofessional forecastersapplythePhillipscurveinsixAsiancountries.

7 Forinstance,Balletal.(2015)testwhetherprofessionalforecastersbelieve intheOkun’sLawwhenmakingtheiroutputandunemploymentpredictionsfor asampleof9advancedcountries.Indeed,theauthorsshowthat,consistentwith Okun’sLaw,forecastsofrealGDPgrowthandthechangeinunemployment arenegativelycorrelated.Previously,Pierdziochetal.(2009)providedsimilar evidencefortheG7countries.

8 Evenifindividualprivatesectorforecastsmaybesubjecttovarious behav-ioralbiases,manyofthesearelikelyto beeliminatedbypoolingforecasts fromseveral individualforecasters.Moreover,ZarnowitzandBraun (1993)

havedocumentedthatgroupmean(“consensus”)forecastsaremoreaccurate thanvirtuallyallindividualforecasts.

we rely on aplethora of time series methodsand regression

analyses.

Our results showthat inflation forecastsinthe region

dis-playthestandardpropertythatastheforecasthorizonshortens

accuracyimproves.Onaverage,forecastersunderpredict

infla-tion,butthismasksverydifferentcountryexperiences.Infact,

Paraguay and Argentina areexamples of countries for which

forecasts are largerthanrealizedinflation,that is,forecasters

overpredictinflation.Wefindevidencepointtobiasednessof

inflationforecastsfor year-aheadforecastsbutnotfor current

year. Asfar as efficiency is concerned,tests’results pointto

inefficiencywhichisalsoevidencedbyatendencytosmooth

forecasts. Inotherwords, informationalrigidities arepresent.

Finally, focusingonbusinesscycle turningpoints,forecasters

tendtoslightlyunderpredicttheinflationrateonaverage,and

the extent of underpredictionseemstoincreaseduring

reces-sions.Thehypothesisofforecastefficiencyisoverwhelmingly

rejectedduringrecessions.Inrecoveryperiods,thehypothesis

ofefficiencyininflationforecastsisalsorejected.

Theremainderofthepaperisorganizedasfollows.Section

2 describes the data andpresents some descriptive statistics.

Section3outlinestheempiricalmethodologyanddiscussesour

main findings. The lastsection concludes andincludes some

policyconsiderations.

2. Dataissuesanddescriptivestatistics

Since the early1990s decade there has been a significant

growthinpublishedeconomicanalysisstemmingfrombanks,

corporationsandindependentconsultantsaroundtheworld,and

a parallel growth in “consensus forecasting” services which

bringtogetherinformationfromthesedifferentprivatesources.

Since1989ConsensusEconomicshaspublishedmonthly

fore-castsformainmacroeconomicvariablespreparedbypanelsof

private sector forecasters. In additionto individual forecasts,

the service publishes thearithmetic averageof each variable,

theso-called“consensusforecast”forthatvariable.Thisseems

a promisingalternative toofficial forecasts for mostusers of

economicforecastsinsteadofsomenaivemodel.9

Thispaperusesthemeanoftheprivateanalysts’monthly

con-sensusforecastsoftheinflationrateforthecurrentandnextyear

fortheperiodfromOctober1989toSeptember2014.Our

sam-pleiscomprisedof14LatinAmericancountries.10The“event”

beingforecastedisannualaverageinflationrate.Everymonth

anewforecastismadeof theevent.Hence,foreachyear,the

sequenceofforecastsisthe24forecastsmadebetweenJanuary

ofthepreviousyearandDecemberoftheyearinquestion.Our

9ThisisacknowledgedbyArtis(1996),whomakesavisualcomparisonof IMFandConsensusEconomicsforecastsforrealGDPandinflation,and con-cludesthatthereis“littledifferencebetweenWEOandConsensuserrors”.Ina similarvein,Loungani(2001)plotsIMFandConsensusEconomicsrealGDP forecastsandnotesthat“theevidencepointstonear-perfectcollinearitybetween privateandofficial(multilateral)forecasts...”

10Countrylistincludes:Argentina,Brazil,Bolivia,Chile,Colombia,Costa Rica,DominicanRepublic,Ecuador,Mexico,Panama,Paraguay,Peru,Uruguay, andVenezuela.

(3)

0 10 0 20 0 30 0 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 year meangr mediangr pctile_75gr pctile_25gr

Fig.1.Interquartilerangeofinflationrate,1989–2014.

Note:Brazilisexcludedfromthesample.Inadditiontothemeaninflation(blue), themedian(red)andtopandbottomquartilesaredisplayed(yellowandgreen, respectively).

Source:IMFIFSandauthors’calculations.

datasetalsoincludesactualdataontheactualinflationratefrom

theInternationalMonetaryFund’sInternationalFinancial

Statis-tics(IMF’sIFS).11 Finally, usingquarterly GDPseries(from

IMF’sIFS),recessionepisodesareidentifiedbasedonthe

clas-sicaldefinitionof abusinesscycleusing quarterlychangesin

the level of real GDP (Burnsand Mitchell, 1946).Countries

areclassifiedasbeinginarecessioninagivensurveymonth

ifthe respectiveforecasted yearfallsinthe recessionyearas

definedfollowingNBER’sapproachfor datingturning points

inthebusinesscycle.Informationondifferentfinancialcrises

comesfromLaevenandValencia’s(2012)database.

Webeginbyplottingtheinterquartilerangeoftheactual

infla-tionrateinoursampleofLatinAmericancountries(excluding

Brazilthatwitnessedseveralhyperinflationepisodesduringthe

1990s).AsshowninFig.1,themeaninflationfortheregionhas

slowlycomedownstartingintheearly1990stostabilizearound

muchlowervalues(historicallyspeaking)sincethe2000s.

Fig.2,plotsthedistributionofinflationforecastsatselected

horizons(h=21,15,9,3)withthedistributionofactual

infla-tionrate.Bothdataandforecastsarepooledacrossthedifferent

countriescomposingourregionalLatinAmericansample.The

keypurposeistoshowthattheforecastsdisplaythereasonable

propertythattheystarttomirrorthedataastheforecasthorizon

drawstoaclose.Asthevalueofh(theforecasthorizon)gets

smaller,thedistributionoftheforecastsstartstomovecloserto

thedistributionofthedata.

11 At this point a caveat should be made. Data revisions have worried economistsformanyyearsnow(seeCroushore,2011forarecentsurvey)and policy-makershavetobasetheirdecisionsonpreliminaryandpartiallyrevised data,sincethemostrecentdataareusuallytheleastreliableasitsimply trans-latesanoisyindicatorforfinalvalues(Koenigetal.,2003).Weareawarethat datarevisionsposechallengestoforecastersandthatforecastingstudiesshould reflectthetrueforecastingperformancebyusingreal-timedatainsteadoffinal data(StarkandCroushore,2002).However,inthepresentcaseitisdifficultto findreliable,consistentandcomparablereal-timevintagesforinflationrates.

Table1

Stylizedfactsoninflationforecastingperformance.

Horizon Pooled Currentyear Yearahead

Sample Allsample,N=14

ME 16.38 11.21 21.55

MAE 22.00 18.18 25.81

RMSE 24201.37 18779.75 29622.99

Sample Allsample,excludingBrazil,N=13

ME 0.396 −0.18 0.97

MAE 3.15 2.30 4.01

RMSE 45.34 28.36 62.33

Notes:Thistablepresentssomedescriptivestatisticsfortheentiresample,as wellasforthesampleexcludingtheoutlierBrazil.ME,MAEandRMSEstand forthemeanforecasterror,theabsoluteforecasterrorandthemeansquare forecasterror,respectively.

Now,forecastingaccuracyshouldcontaintwoaspectsofthe

forecastascomparedtotheactualoutcome(MussoandPhillips,

2002).Thefirstoneishowclosebothareinquantitativeterms

bymeansofanumberof“standardmeasures”,whilethesecond

onereferstothecapacityof theforecast topredictthe

direc-tionofchangeinthefinaloutcome.Define,foreachcountryi

duringyeart,eit=AitFit,whereerepresentsforecasterror,

Fdenotestheforecast,andAdenotesitsrespectiverealization

(inourcaseitcorrespondstothemoving averageof monthly

reported inflationrates). In terms of “standardmeasures” we

usethreeconventionalerrormeasurestoassessrelative

perfor-mance:theaverageforecastbias(ME),12themeanabsoluteerror

(MAE)andtherootmeansquarederror(RMSE).Whilethese

measureshaveanumberoflimitations,theRMSEhasinvariably

beenusedasstandardforjudgingthequalityofpredictions.13

TheME,MAEandRMSEstatisticsarereportedinTable1.14

Themean errorispositiveandmuchlargerthanonepoint

whenwepoolallcountriestogether,includingBrazil.However,

this masks very different country experiences and excluding

Brazilgivesaconsiderablybetterpicture fortheperformance

ofinflationforecasts.Focusingonthebottompanel,themean

errorremainspositive(meaningthatinflationisunder-predicted)

butsmallerthanonepoint(withtheabsoluteerroronlyslightly

larger). Splitting the sample between current and year-ahead

forecastsalsouncoversinterestingfindings.Incurrentyear

fore-casts,thereisinfact overpredictionof inflation(asshownby

thecoefficientof−0.18).Notsurprisingly,absoluteerrors

(irre-spectivelyofthesampleunderscrutiny)arealwayssmallerfor

currentyearthanforyearaheadforecasts(inlinewithevidence

presentedinFig.1aboutforecastsconvergingtoactualsasthe

12Definedastheaveragedifferencebetweentheactualvalueanditsforecasted value.Forexample,apositivevalueforbiasindicatesthatonaverageoverthe wholerunofforecastsfortheinflationrate,theactualvaluewasunder-estimated, sothattheforecastsweretoolow.

13TheRMSEmaybethemostpopularmeasureamongstatisticianspartially becauseofitsmathematicaltractability.Morerecently,researchersseemto pre-fertheso-calledPercentBetter,theMeanAbsolutePercentageErrorandthe RelativeAbsoluteError.ForareviewseeArmstrongandCollopy(1992).

14Thesametablewasalsodonesplittingthesampleintwotimeperiods,from 1989until2002andfrom2003until2014.Forreasonsofeconomyofspace, resultsareavailableuponrequest.

(4)

Fig.2. Distributionofactualandforecastedinflationrate,1989–2014. Source:Consensus,IMFIFSandauthors’calculations.

horizondrawstoaclose).Thisseems,onaverage,arelatively

goodperformanceforinflationforecastsintheregionasresults

provideevidenceofhardlyenormouserrorstraditionally.Infact,

therelationshipbetweeninflationandtheaccuracyofinflation

predictions inhigh-inflation countries,such as thoseinLatin

America,tendstobenegative(seeMaskusandPourgerami,1990

andreferencestherein).Thereasonforthepotentiallynegative

effectofinflationoninflationuncertainty(whereuncertaintyis

equated withlackof predictability) isthat inahigh-inflation

environmenteconomicagentsinvestmoreresourcesin

gener-atingaccurateinflationforecastsandindevelopinginstruments

capableofreducingtheuncertaintycostsofhighinflation.

AsEdwards(1993)putsit,“contrarilytopopularmythology,

notallcountriesinLatinAmericahavehadlonginflationary

his-tories”.Moreover,asIMF(2016a)pointsout,the“regionalmix”

intermsofeconomicoutlooksisimpressive.Thesetwogiveus

sufficientreasonstoinspect inflationforecastingperformance

country-by-country.Fig.3showsthecountry-by-countrymean

errorforbothcurrentandyear-aheadforecasts.Someinteresting

differencescanbehighlighted.First,ParaguayandArgentinaare

examplesofcountriesforwhichforecastsarelargerthan

real-izedinflation,thatis,forecastersoverpredictinflation.Onthe

contrary,forMexico,Ecuador,DominicanRepublicandCosta

Rica theoppositeapplies.Countriesforwhichthemeanerror

isrelativelysmallerorclosetozeroisUruguay,Colombiaand

Chile(forbothforecasthorizons).

3. Methodologyandresults

3.1. Anassessmentofthequalityofinflationforecasts 3.1.1. Rationalityofinflationforecasts

Thekeyforanassessmenton“rationality”or“unbiasedness”

lies, firstly,in the available informationat the timethe

fore-castwaselaborated(data,policymeasures),andsecondlyinthe

(5)

Argenna Bolivia Chile Colombia Costa Rica Dominican Republic Ecuador Mexico Panama Paraguay Peru Uruguay Venezuela

Fig.3.Meanforecasterrorbyhorizon. Source:Consensus,IMFIFSandauthors’calculations.

benchmarkstandards,aswedidintheprevioussection,

deter-mineswhichonehassmallererrors;itdoesnotindicatehowto

improveupontheobservedrecord.Rationalitytestsdetermine

whetherornotthepredictionsareoptimalwithregardstoa

par-ticularinformationset(Wallis,1989).Aforecastisunbiasedif

itsaveragedeviationfromtheoutcomeiszero.15Wetestforthe

presenceofbiasininflationforecasterrorsbyadoptinga

statis-ticalapproachandconsideringsymmetriclossfunctionsonthe

partoftheagenciesgeneratingtheforecasts.Weuse:

At+hFt+h=α+εt+h (1)

wheretheforecasthorizonh=1,...,24.At+histheactualvalue

of variablex int+h, and Ft+h isthe forecast for t+h made

att. Ft+h is unbiased if we cannot reject the null hypothesis

thatα=0(HoldenandPeel,1990).Iftheestimatedcoefficient

is significantly larger or smaller than zero, the forecasts are

biased towardoptimism or pessimism,respectively. This last

pointiscloselyrelatedtoabehavioraleconomicsconcept:the

anchoringheuristic (Tversky andKahneman, 1974) whichis

increasinglyconsideredwhenexplainingbiasedforecasts.The

underlyingmechanismistypicallydescribedasinHarvey(2007)

whostates that forecasterstendto“usethe lastdatapoint in

theseries asamentalanchorandthenadjustaway fromthat

anchor totake account of the major feature(s) of the series.

However,asadjustmentistypicallyinsufficient,theirforecasts

arebiased”.16Anotherprominentexplanationofsystematically

biasedforecastspointstoreputational concernsof forecasters

tryingtostrategically concealtheir inabilityto predict future

values.Thisresults instrong incentives for herdingbehavior

15 Asarule,ifforecastsareinlinewiththeRationalExpectationsHypothesis (REH)formulatedbyMuth(1961),theyshouldbeunbiased.TheREHstates thatmarketparticipantsuseallcost-efficientknowledgetoforecast.

16 Therearemanytimeseriesforecastingexperimentsinvestigatingindividual predictionbehavior(e.g.ReimersandHarvey,2011).

Table2 Rationalitytest.

Horizon Pooled Currentyear Yearahead

Sample Allsample,excludingBrazil

α 0.396*** −0.180 0.972*** (0.111) (0.124) (0.182) Country Argentina α −2.672*** −3.733*** −1.61** (0.644) (1.035) (0.761) Country Bolivia α −0.023 −0.287* 0.241 (0.168) (0.151) (0.299) Country Chile α 0.178* 0.168* 0.189 (0.095) (0.099) (0.163) Country Colombia α 0.173** 0.167** 0.178 (0.086) (0.078) (0.155)

Country CostaRica

α 1.558*** 0.884*** 2.232***

(0.167) (0.178) (0.272)

Country DominicanRepublic

α 2.726*** 1.435*** 4.016*** (0.640) (0.545) (1.150) Country Ecuador α 3.621*** 2.205*** 5.036*** (0.714) (0.663) (1.256) Country Mexico α 1.335*** 0.675*** 1.996*** (0.248) (0.246) (0.425) Country Panama α 0.073 −0.123 0.270 (0.107) (0.102) (0.187) Country Paraguay α −1.911*** −2.092*** −1.730*** (0.269) (0.336) (0.421) Country Peru α −0.499*** −0.062 −0.937*** (0.145) (0.149) (0.245) Country Uruguay α −0.006 −0.140 0.128 (0.249) (0.284) (0.411) Country Venezuela α 0.346 −1.668*** 2.360** (0.611) (0.558) (1.061)

Note:ThedependentvariableisConsensusforecasterror.Eachcellreports theresultsofaregressionofforecasterrorsonaconstantforthepoolofall countriesinoursample(thatexcludesBrazil)and eachindividualcountry. Heteroskedastic-consistentrobuststandarderrorsarereportedinparenthesis.

* Indicatessignificanceat10%level. **Indicatessignificanceat5%level. ***Indicatessignificanceat1%level.

amongforecasters(OttavianiandSørensen,2006;Ackertetal.,

2008).

Table2reports,forcurrentandyear-ahead,andforthepooled

sampleandeachcountryindividually,thet-testsforα=0.For

(6)

forecastsonlyinyear-aheadforecastsbutnotfor current-year

ones(theseseemunbiased).Asbefore,giventheregionalmix,

countryresultshideagreatdealofheterogeneity.More

specif-ically,inthecasesofPanamaandUruguay,inflationforecasts

seemunbiasedirrespectivelyoftheforecasthorizonconsidered.

Fortheremainderofthecountries,thenullhypothesisofrational

forecastscanberejectedineitheroneorbothhorizons.17

3.1.2. EfficiencyofInflationforecasts

AccordingtoNordhaus(1987)asequenceofefficient

fore-castsofthesameeventmustfollowamartingale.AsinGentry

(1989),we regressactualobservations onaconstantplusthe forecast:

At+h=α+βFt+h+εt+h (2)

wheretheforecasthorizonh=1,...,24.At+histheactualvalue

ofvariablexint+h,andFt+histheforecastfort+hmadeatt.

Ft+hisefficientifwecannotrejectthenullhypothesisthatα=0

andβ=1individuallyandjointly.

AsTable3shows,inallforecasthorizons,thejoint

hypothe-sisofazeroconstantandaslopecoefficientofunityisrejected,

asindicatedbytheF-statisticsandassociatedp-values.18 This

pointstoinefficiencyofinflationforecasts.Sincethedataare

pooledacrosscountriesandovertime, thereisreasonto

sus-pect that the disturbance term, εt+h,in Eq. (2) would not be

random.Weattemptedtocontrolforsomeofthepossible

cor-relations by augmentingthe regression to include year fixed

effects.Theideaisthat someyearsmaybehardertoforecast

thanothers.Ourresults (notshown)still suggestinefficiency.

Asbefore,thepooledresultshideheterogeneityandinBolivia,

Chile,Colombia,DominicanRepublic,MexicoandVenezuela,

thejointhypothesisisnotrejected.Thissuggeststhat,forthis

groupofcountries,inflationforecastsmayhavebeenefficient

overtheperiodunderscrutiny.

3.1.3. From“forecast(in-)efficiency”to“informational rigidity”

Adifferentapproachtotackleforecastefficiency was

sug-gestedbyNordhaus(1987)whodefinedanotionofefficiency

or“informationrigidity”basedonforecastrevisions.Nordhaus

(1987) and Nordhaus and Durlauf (1984) studied “forecast

smoothing”, i.e., a tendency for a revision in one direction

to be followedby further revisions inthe same direction, in

fixed-eventforecasts.Thisisanimplicationoffull-informational

17Itisworthpointingtothepossibilitythatmanyoftherejectionsofforecast optimalitymaysimplybedrivenbytheassumptionofMSElossratherthanthe absenceofforecastrationalityperse.Elliotetal.(2005)statethatMSEloss, despiteagenerallyusedassumption,isoftenhardtojustifyoneconomicgrounds andissubjecttodebateandcriticism.Infact,asymmetriclosscapturestheidea thatthecostofover-andunderpredictingagivenvariablemaybeverydifferent.

PattonandTimmermann(2007)proposeatransformationoftheforecasterror thatpossessesthesamesetofrationalitypropertiesunderasymmetriclossand nonlineardatageneratingprocesses.

18WepickOctoberandAprilofthecurrentyearandyear-aheadasexamples ofthefirstandsecondhalfofagivenforecastyear.Arbitraryselectionof dif-ferentadjacentmonths(recallthatwehaveacontinuoussequenceof24months forecast)doesnotqualitativelyalterourresults.

rationalexpectations(FIRE):successiveforecastsofthesame

event shouldbeuncorrelated.19 Recent papers addressingthe

issueofinformationrigidityonmacroforecastsincludeIsiklar

etal.(2006),Lounganietal.(2013),CoibionandGorodnichenko (2015)andJallesetal.(2015).

We defineinitial revisionof the forecast as the change in

the forecast betweenOctober andAprilof the previousyear,

themiddlerevisionasthechangebetweenAprilofthecurrent

yearandOctoberofthepreviousyear,andthefinalrevisionas

the change betweenOctoberof the current yearandAprilof

thecurrentyear.Resultsfromregressionsoflaterrevisionson

earlierones areshowninTable4.Inall,butone,regressions,

thereisevidenceofastrongpositivecorrelationamongforecast

revisions(atthe1%significancelevel).Overall,thereisaclear

tendencyfor“forecastsmoothing”,i.e.,theestimatedcoefficient

onthelaggedrevisionpointstothepresenceof informational

rigidities.Infact,lookingatthespecificationwithbothmiddle

andinitialrevisionsincludedtogether,it takesbetween1and

1.2 months for the information to be fully incorporated into

forecasts.20

Alternatively, following Coibion and Gorodnichenko’s

(2015) approachweregress theforecast erroronthe forecast

revisionusingourfinal,middleorinitialrevisions.Theauthors

showthatthecoefficientontheforecastrevisioniszerounderthe

nulloffullinformationalrationalexpectations,whereasa

posi-tivevalueindicatesinformationrigidities.21Table5presentsthe

resultsofthistestandweobservethatthecoefficientestimates

areallpositiveandstatisticallydifferentfromzero.Thenullcan

be rejectedandthisfact goesinthe directionconsistentwith

modelswithinformationrigidity.Inthiscase,ittakesbetween

1.2and1.6monthsforinformationtobefullyincorporated.22

Overall,wecanconcludethatinflationrateforecastsare

ineffi-cient.

3.2. Inflationforecasts,recessionsandturningpoints

The recentGlobalFinancialCrisishas revivedtheinterest

not onlyin predicting recessions but also on the forecasting

performanceandaccuracyofmanymacroaggregatesthatcould

helpdeterminingupwardanddownwardmovementsinthe

busi-nesscycle(anditscorrespondingturningpoints).Wenowturn

to the examination of the inflation rate forecast performance

19Theliteraturehasidentifiedthreemainpotentialexplanationsfor“forecast smoothing”or“informationrigidity”(fordeparturefromFIRE):(i)behavioral explanations(Nordhaus,1987);(ii)sticky-information(MankiwandReis,2002) and(iii)imperfectinformation(Woodford,2002).

20MankiwandReis(2002)proposeamodelofinattentiveagentswhoupdate theirinformationsetseachperiodwithprobability(1−λ),butacquirenonew informationwithprobabilityλ,sothatλcanbeinterpretedasthedegreeof informationrigidityand1/(1−λ)istheaveragedurationbetweeninformation updates.Inthecontextofstickyinformationmodels,λ=β/(1+β),withβbeing theestimatedrigiditycoefficient.

21Onefeatureofthistestisthatitrequirestheuseoftheactualrealizations andhencerequiresaviewonwhethertousethelatestdataoranearliervintage. Ourtestsusethelatestdata.

22CoibionandGorodnichenko(2012)reportforinflationsimilarspeedforthe updatingofforecasts(1.5–2months).

(7)

Table3

Gentry’s(1989)Testofforecastefficiency.

Sample/country Independentvariables Dependentvariable:“actual”inflationrate

Apr.(t−1) Oct.(t−1) Apr.(t) Oct.(t)

All Constant −2.242 −0.470 5.615 2.034 (9.902) (5.137) (6.976) (6.481) Forecast 2.095*** 1.571*** 1.088*** 1.111*** (0.114) (0.038) (0.027) (0.026) F-statistic 47.85 114.70 6.18 9.38 p-Value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Argentina F-statistic(p-value) 0.12 0.01 0.00 0.00

Bolivia F-statistic(p-value) 0.46 0.69 0.61 0.21

Chile F-statistic(p-value) 0.35 0.91 0.59 0.36

Colombia F-statistic(p-value) 0.79 0.91 0.99 0.77

CostaRica F-statistic(p-value) 0.01 0.09 0.12 0.68

DominicanRepublic F-statistic(p-value) 0.25 0.59 0.33 0.04

Ecuador F-statistic(p-value) 0.02 0.03 0.00 0.09

Mexico F-statistic(p-value) 0.29 0.19 0.12 0.17

Panama F-statistic(p-value) 0.89 0.59 0.01 0.22

Paraguay F-statistic(p-value) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Peru F-statistic(p-value) 0.00 0.00 0.06 0.00

Uruguay F-statistic(p-value) 0.18 0.34 0.52 0.83

Venezuela F-statistic(p-value) 0.25 0.27 0.62 0.70

Notes:Theregressionisexpressedas,whereAistheactualrealizationandFistheforecast.TheF-statisticandassociatedp-valueareforthetestofthenullhypothesis thatβ0=0andβ1=1.Forcountry-levelresultsfullsetofcoefficientsandrespectivestatisticsareavailableuponrequest;theywereomittedforreasonsofparsimony. Heteroskedastic-consistentrobuststandarderrorsarereportedinparenthesis.

*Indicatessignificanceat10%level. **Indicatessignificanceat5%level. ***Indicatessignificanceat1%level.

Table4

Nordhaus’(1987)Testofforecastefficiency.

Sample Dependentvariable Independentvariables R-squared

Middlerevision Initialrevision Constant

All Finalrevision 0.239*** 0.083 0.03

(0.018) (0.063) Finalrevision 0.029*** −0.007 0.04 (0.008) (0.057) Finalrevision 0.240*** 0.013* −0.026 0.04 (0.018) (0.007) (0.058) Middlerevision 0.029 0.02 (0.039)

Note:Thedependentvariableisidentifiedincolumn2aseitherFinalRevisionorMiddleRevision.Asfortheindependentvariablesincludedineachregression, theseareidentifiedincolumns3and4togetherwithaconstantterm(column5).Heteroskedastic-consistentrobuststandarderrorsarereportedinparenthesis. **Indicatessignificanceat5%level.

* Indicatessignificanceat10%level. ***Indicatessignificanceat1%level.

duringrecessionepisodes,usingdescriptivestatisticalanalysis

andsimpleregressions.Itisimportanttolookatthebehavior

ofinflationforecasts indifferent phasesof thebusiness cycle

duetoseveralreasons:(1) thisiswhengeneralinterest(from

practitionersandpolicymakers) inpredictingthisvariableis

highest;(2)differentcentralbanksinLatinAmericamayhave

differentiatedobjectives(somemaybeconcerned solelywith

inflationwhileothersarewiderandincludeoutput,stabilityand

employmentconsiderations)whichtiefuturepolicyactionsto

alternative levels ofinflationrate23;(3) inflationexpectations

candramaticallychange around turningpoints.24 Somebasic

propertiesoftheinflationrateforecastsduringrecessionyears

aresummarizedinTable6.

Asshowninthefirstrow,asofApriloftheyearpreceding

the recession,theconsensusinflationforecastsweretoo

opti-23SeeCecchettiandEhrmann(2002)foranexaminationofthecentralbank objectivefunctionsinalargenumberofadvancedandemergingeconomies.

24SeeJalilandRua(2015)forevidence,usingnarrativerecords,onhowthe GreatDepressionintheUSin1933hasshiftedinflationexpectations.

(8)

Table5

CoibionandGorodnichenko’s(2015)Testofforecastefficiency.

Sample Independentvariables R-squared

Finalrevision Middlerevision Initialrevision Constant

All 0.514*** 0.382*** 0.09 (0.026) (0.111) 0.291*** 0.082 0.07 (0.014) (0.112) 0.201*** 0.402*** 0.23 (0.041) (0.114) 0.624*** 0.285*** 0.411*** 0.037 0.22 (0.027) (0.013) (0.038) (0.106)

Notes:Thedependentvariableistheinflationforecasterror.Asfortheindependentvariablesincludedineachregression,theseareidentifiedincolumns2–4together withaconstantterm(column5).Heteroskedastic-consistentrobuststandarderrorsarereportedinparenthesis.

*Indicatessignificanceat10%level. **Indicatessignificanceat5%level. ***Indicatessignificanceat1%level.

Table6

Forecastperformanceofconsensusinflationrateduringrecessionepisodes.

Allcountries Apr.(t−1) Oct.(t−1) Apr.(t) Oct.(t)

Numberofepisodeswhereforecast wastoooptimistic(forecast<actual) (shareintotal,inpercentage)

10(45) 12(46) 9(35) 4(18)

Averageforecasterror(allrecession episodes)

6.19 4.36 −2.68 −3.44

Note:Refertothemaintextfordetails.

Table7

DescriptiveStatisticsofConsensusInflationForecastsduringRecessionsandRecoveries.

Forecasterrors Absoluteforecasterrors Forecasterrors Absoluteforecasterrors Forecasterrors Absoluteforecasterrors

Spec. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Allcountries Unconditional Recessions Recoveries

Mean 0.39 3.15 1.18 8.42 0.47 6.62

Standarddeviation 6.72 5.94 14.14 11.41 10.79 8.76

Minimum -65.66 0.00 -65.66 0.02 -34.08 0.02

Maximum 69.85 69.85 46.02 65.66 46.02 46.02

mistic(definedasforecastsmallerthanactualrealization)in10

episodes corresponding to45% of the totalnumberof

reces-sionepisodes.By Apriloftheyearof therecession, inflation

forecastsweretoooptimisticinonly35% ofthetotalnumber

ofepisodes.Whileforecastersdorecognizeaslowdowninthe

inflationrateduringrecessionsintheyearinwhichtheyoccur,

resultsseemtosuggestthattheycannotanticipatesuch

down-wardrevisionintheyearprecedingtherecession.Moreover,as

showninthefinalrow,thereisasignificantupwardbiasinthe

year-aheadAprilforecaststhatonlyslowlydissipatesovertime;

wegofromameanerrorabove6pointsinApriloftheyear

pre-cedingtherecession,toameanerrorof−3pointsintheyearof

therecession.

Fig.4 presentsagraphicalsummaryof theME,MAEand

RMSEdescriptivestatistics byforecasthorizon. Aswe move

fromyear-aheadtowardscurrent-year,weseeasteadilydecline

inboththeMAEandMSE(unconditionalline).Moreover,we

havepositivevaluesforthemeanforecasterrorsformostofthe

24-monthforecasthorizonmeaningthatforecasters

underesti-matetheinflationrate.Lookingattherecession(blue)line,we

observethatittakessometimeforforecasterstorecognizethat

theeconomyishittingarecession.

In Table7,we see that forecasters tendto slightly

under-predict the inflation rate on average, and the extent of

underpredictionseemstoincreaseduringrecessions.The

regres-sionanalysisconfirmsthatastheforecasthorizonincreasesso

dotheabsoluteforecasterrors(Table8).Moreover,the

reces-sions’dummyisstatisticallydifferentfromzeroandpositively

correlatedwithabsoluteforecasterrors.

3.2.1. Ontheefficiencypropertiesofinflationforecasts duringrecessions

Wenowexamineforecastefficiencybyconductingtwotypes

of tests. The first is due to Nordhaus (1987) who defined a

notion of “information rigidity” based on forecast revisions

inlinewiththefullinformationrationalexpectations’ (FIRE)

premise thatsuccessive revisionsshouldbeuncorrelated. The

(9)

Recessions Recoveries Unconditional

Mean Errors

0 20 40 60 80 1 3 6 9 12 15 18 21 24

Mean Absolute Errors

0 50 10 0 1 3 6 9 12 15 18 21 24

Root Mean Squared Errors

0 10 0 20 0 30 0 40 0 1 3 6 9 12 15 18 21 24 g g p g Forecast Horizon

Fig.4.Descriptivestatisticsinflationrateforecasterrors:consensus1989–2014. Source:Consensus,IMFIFSandauthors’calculations.

Table8

RegressionofInflationRateForecastErrorsonDifferentStatesoftheEconomy.

Sample Allsample

Horizon Pooled Currentyear Yearahead

Recessions 5.708*** 5.212*** 6.235*** (0.344) (0.397) (0.574) Recoveries 3.325*** 1.874*** 4.936*** (0.312) (0.362) (0.518) Horizon 0.155*** 0.135*** 0.107* (0.016) (0.039) (0.056) Constant 0.305 0.671** 0.902 (0.243) (0.291) (1.049) Obs. 2878 1511 1367 R-squared 0.165 0.144 0.159

Notes:Thedependentvariable isabsolute forecasterrors. Heteroskedastic-consistentrobuststandarderrorsarereportedinparenthesis.

* Indicatessignificanceat10%level. ** Indicatessignificanceat5%level. ***Indicatessignificanceat1%level.

observationson aconstantplus the forecast errorandjointly

testsefficiency by imposing azero intercept andunity slope

coefficient.

WefirstrunNordhaus’(1987)regressionswiththeinclusion

ofdummiesforbankingcrisisandforrecessionandrecoveries

episodestoascertaindifferencesininflationforecasts’efficiency

duringtheseeventscomparedtoaverages.Theresultssuggest

that onaverageforecastsare inefficient(Table9).Lookingat

specification3,duringrecessions,onecanseethatmiddleand

initialrevisionsinonedirectiongenerallyarefollowedbyfinal

revisionsinthesamedirection(thecoefficientsonmiddleand

initialrevisionsafterrecessionsarestatisticallysignificant).

Finally,followingGentry’s (1989)approachdefined above

wedisplaytheresultsforthejointhypothesistestingfortheslope

andinterceptcoefficientsusingtheWaldtestsinTable10.The

hypothesis of forecast efficiency is overwhelmingly rejected,

includingforrecessionepisodes.

3.2.2. Ontheefficiencypropertiesofinflationforecasts duringrecoveries

Theaboveanalysisdocumentedfailuresinforecasting

infla-tionduringrecessions.Naturallyaquestionarisesaboutinflation

forecastperformanceduringrecoveries,anotherturningpointof

thebusinesscycle.Weexplorethisquestionbriefly.InFig.4,

lookingattherecoveries’line,weobservethat,meanerrorsof

(10)

Table9

Nordhaus’(1987)Testofefficiencybasedoninflationforecastrevisionsandaccountingforrecessionandrecoveryepisodes.

Dependentvariable Finalrevisions

Sample Allsample

Spec. (1) (2) (3)

Constant −0.373 −0.938*** −0.168

(0.814) (0.331) (0.288)

Dummyforrecession 1.294 4.595*** −1.250*

(1.979) (0.722) (0.682)

Dummyforrecovery −11.094*** 1.561** −0.939*

(1.658) (0.652) (0.582)

Dummyforbankingcrisis 5.156* 3.613*** 3.106***

(2.725) (1.252) (1.152)

Middlerevision 0.496*** −0.564***

(0.099) (0.035)

Middlerevisionafterrecessions −0.611*** 0.682***

(0.056) (0.023)

Middlerevisionrecoveries 2.186*** 0.564***

(0.099) (0.035)

Middlerevisionafterbankingcrisis 0.652*** 3.732***

(0.104) (0.589)

Initialrevision −0.081*** −0.017**

(0.009) (0.008)

Initialrevisionafterrecessions 0.419*** 0.188***

(0.015) (0.015)

Initialrevisionrecoveries 2.083*** 2.007***

(0.010) (0.013)

Initialrevisionafterbankingcrisis −0.574*** 1.179***

(0.010) (0.338)

Obs. 4435 4089 4089

R-squared 0.87 0.98 0.98

Notes:Thedependentvariableistheinflationratefinalrevisions.Regressionsincludedummyvariablesforrecessionandrecoveryepisodes.Heteroskedastic-consistent robuststandarderrorsarereportedinparenthesis.

* Indicatessignificanceat10%level. **Indicatessignificanceat5%level. ***Indicatessignificanceat1%level.

variablecomparedtotheunconditionalbut,moreimportantly,

tomeanerrorsduringrecessions.Alsoittakesforecastersmuch

longerfortheconvergencewiththeunconditionallinetohappen.

Themainfindinghereisthatwhileduringrecoveries,

infla-tion is more often accurately predicted than in recessions

(Table7),regressionresultssuggestthatinflationforecastsare

equally as inefficient as those taking placeduring recessions

(Tables8and9).Moreover,duringrecoveriesmostforecasters

reviseupwardstheirinflationpredictions(Fig.5).Hence,there

is asense of “optimism”that the average economy’s growth

ispickingupwhichdriveinflationexpectationstowardshigher

levels.Allinall,ourresultssuggest“informationrigidity”in

forecastsalsoduringrecoveries.

4. Conclusion

Thispaper providesafullcharacterization ofinflationrate

forecastsusingthemeanvaluesfromConsensusEconomicsfor

a sample of 14 Latin American countriesbetween 1989 and

2014.Italsoassessestheperformanceofinflationrateforecasts

aroundbusinesscycles’turningpoints.Tothisend,wereliedon

aplethoraoftimeseriesmethodsandregressionanalyses.

0 10 0 20 0 30 0 1 3 6 9 12 15 18 21 24

1 year after recession

Fig.5.Actualandforecastedinflationrateduringrecoveries(upto1yearafter recessionended):1989–2014.

Source:Consensus,IMFIFSandauthors’calculations.

Ourresultsshowthatinflationforecastsintheregiondisplay

the standardpropertythat theystarttomirror the dataas the

(11)

fore-Table10

Gentry’s(1989)Testofforecastefficiencyunderrecessionsandrecoveries.

Sample All

Spec. (1)

Constant −0.382

(0.257)

Dummyforrecession 6.828***

(0.633)

Dummyforrecovery 0.838

(0.572)

Dummyforbankingcrisis −0.443

(0.965)

Forecast 0.994***

(0.018)

Forecastafterrecession −0.275***

(0.025)

Forecastafterrecovery −0.016

(0.027)

Forecastafterbankingcrisis 0.154***

(0.045)

Obs. 2676

R-squared 0.75

P-valuesforWaldtests

Forecastafterrecessions 0.04

Forecastafterrecession 0.00

Forecastafterrecovery 0.00

Forecastafterbankingcrisis 0.00

Notes:Thedependentvariableisactualvaluesofinflationrate.Thehypothesis fortheWaldtestisthatthevalueoftherespectivetotaleffectisnot statisti-callydifferentfromzero.Heteroskedastic-consistentrobuststandarderrorsare reportedinparenthesis.

*Indicatessignificanceat10%level. **Indicatessignificanceat5%level. ***Indicatessignificanceat1%level.

casterrorispositive,suggestingunderpredictionofinflation,but

thismasksverydifferentcountryexperiences.Infact,Paraguay

andArgentina are examples of countries for whichforecasts

arelargerthanrealizedinflation,thatis,forecastersoverpredict

inflation.Wefindevidencepointtobiasednessofinflation

fore-castsforyear-aheadforecastsbutnotforcurrentyear.Asfaras

efficiencyisconcerned,tests’resultspointtoinefficiencywhich

isalsoevidencedbyatendencytosmoothforecasts(forecast

revisionsinonedirectionarefollowingbysubsequentrevisions

inthesamedirection).Thismeansthatinformationalrigidities

arepresent,takingonaverage1.5monthsforinformationtobe

fullyincorporatedandinternalized.

Finally,focusingonbusinesscycleturningpoints,while

fore-castersdo recognize aslowdown in the inflation rate during

recessionsintheyearinwhichtheyoccur,resultsseemto

sug-gestthattheycannotanticipateadownwardrevisionininflation

forecastsintheyearprecedingtherecession. Moreover,

fore-casterstendtoslightlyunderpredicttheinflationrateonaverage,

andtheextentofunderpredictionseemstoincreaseduring

reces-sions.Thehypothesisofforecastefficiencyisoverwhelmingly

rejectedduringrecessions.Inrecoveries,thereisageneralsense

of“optimism”thattheaverageeconomy’sgrowthispickingup

whichdriveinflationexpectationstowardshigherlevels.

References

Ackert,L.F.,Church,B.K.,Ely,K.,2008.Biasesinindividualforecasts: exper-imentalevidence.J.Behav.Finance9,53–61.

Armstrong,J.S.,Collopy,F.,1992.Errormeasuresforgeneralizingabout fore-castingmethods:empiricalcomparisons.Int.J.Forecast.8,69–80.

Artis,M.J.,1996.HowaccuratearetheIMF’sshorttermforecasts?Another examinationoftheWorldEconomicOutlook,IMFResearchDepartment WorkingPaper.

Baer,W.,1967.TheinflationcontroversyinLatinAmerica:asurvey.LatinAm. Res.Rev.2(2),3–25.

Ball,L.,Jalles,J.T.,Loungani,P.,2015.DoforecastersbelieveinOkun’slaw? Anassessmentofunemploymentandoutputforecasts.Int.J.Forecast.31 (1),176–184.

Barro,RobertJ.,1995.InflationandEconomicGrowth,NBERWorkingPaper 5326.

Batchelor,R.,Dua,P.,1992.Conservatismandconsensus-seekingamong eco-nomicforecasters.J.Forecast.11,169–181.

Bova,E.,Jalles,J.T.,Kolerus,C.,2016.Shiftingthebeveridgecurve:what affectslabormarketmatching?Int.LaborRev.,forthcoming.

Burns,A.F.,Mitchell,W.C.,1946.MeasuringBusinessCycles.NationalBureau ofEconomicResearch,NewYork,NewYork.

Cecchetti, S.,Ehrmann,M.,2002. Doesinflationtargeting increaseoutput volatility?Aninternational comparisonofpolicymakerspreferencesand outcomes.In:Loayza,Norman,Schmidt-Hebbel,Klaus(Eds.),Monetary Policy:RulesandTransmissionMechanisms.CentralBankofChile, Santi-ago,pp.247–274.

Coibion,O.,Gorodnichenko,Y.,2012.Whatcansurveyforecaststellusabout informationrigidities?J.PoliticalEcon.120(1),116–159.

Coibion,O.,Gorodnichenko,Y.,2015.Informationrigidityandtheexpectations formationprocess:asimpleframeworkandnewfacts.Am.Econ.Rev.105 (8),2644–2678.

Cole,JulioH.,1987.LatinAmericanInflation:TheoreticalInterpretationsand EmpiricalResults.Praeger,NewYork.

Croushore,D.,2011.Frontiersofreal-timedataanalysis.J.Econ.Lit.49(1), 72–100.

DeGregorio,J.,1993.Inflation,taxation,andlong-rungrowth.J.Monet.Econ. 31,271–298.

Edwards,S.1993.ThePoliticalEconomyofInflationandstabilizationin devel-opingcountries”:NBERworkingpaperNo.4319.

Elliot,G.,Komunjer,I., Timmermann,A.,2005.Estimationand testingof forecastrationalityunderflexibleloss.Rev.Econ.Studies72,1107–1125.

Fendel,R.,Lis,E.,Rülke,J.C.,2011.Doprofessionalforecastersbelievein thephillipscurve?—EvidencefromtheG7countries.J.Forecast.30(2), 268–287.

Fisher,S.,1993.Theroleofmacroeconomicfactorsingrowth.J.Monet.Econ. 32,485–512.

Gentry,W.M.,1989.Dostaterevenueforecastersutilizeavailableinformation? Natl.TaxJ.42,429–439.

Harvey,N.,2007.Useofheuristics:insightsfromforecastingresearch.Think. Reason.13(1),5–24.

Holden,K.,Peel,D.A.,1990.Ontestingforunbiasednessandefficiencyof forecasts.Manch.School63,120–127.

IMF,2016a.TooSlowforTooLong.InternationalMonetaryFund,Washington DC,April.

IMF,2016b.RegionalEconomicOutlook:WesternHemisphere—Managing TransitionsandRisks.InternationalMonetaryFund,WashingtonDC,April.

Isiklar,G.,Lahiri,K.,Loungani,P.,2006.Howquicklydoforecasters incorpo-ratenews?J.Appl.Econometr.21,703–725.

Jalil,A.,Rua,G.,2015.InflationExpectationsandRecoveryfromthe Depres-sionin1933:EvidencefromtheNarrativeRecordFinanceandEconomics DiscussionSeries2015-029.BoardofGovernorsoftheFederalReserve System,Washington.

Jalles,J.T.,Karibzhanov,I.,Loungani,P.,2015.Cross-countryevidenceonthe qualityoffiscalforecasts.J.Macroecon.45,186–201.

Koenig,E.F.,Dolmas,S.,Piger,J.,2003.Theuseandabuseofreal-timedatain economicforecasting.Rev.Econ.Stat.85(3),618–628.

(12)

Laeven,L.,Valencia,F.,2012.SystemicBankingCrisesDatabase:AnUpdate, IMFWP12/163.InternationalMonetaryFund,WashingtonDC.

Loungani,P.,2001.Howaccurateareprivatesectorforecasts?Cross-country evidencefromconsensusforecastsofoutputgrowth.Int.J.Forecast.17, 419–432.

Loungani,P.,Stekler,H.,Tamirisa,N.,2013.Informationrigidityingrowth forecasts:somecross-countryevidence.Int.J.Forecast.29(4),605–621.

Mankiw,N.G.,Reis,R.,2002.Stickyinformationversusstickyprices:aproposal toreplacethenewKeynesianPhillipsCurve.Q.J.Econ.117(4),1295–1328.

Maskus, K.,Pourgerami,A.,1990.Inflationand itspredictability in high-inflation Latin American countries: some evidence on two competing hypotheses—aresearchnote.J.Int.Dev.2(3),373–379.

Musso,A.,Phillips,S.,2002.ComparingProjectionsandOutcomesof IMF-SupportedPrograms,IMFStaffPapers,49(1).

Muth,J.,1961.Rationalexpectationsandthetheoryofpricemovements. Econo-metrica29,315–335.

Nordhaus,W.D.,1987.Forecastingefficiency:conceptsandapplications.Rev. Econ.Stat.69,667–674.

Nordhaus,W.,Durlauf,S.,1984,EmpiricalTestsoftheRationalityofEconomic Forecasters:AFixedHorizonsApproach,CowlesFoundationDiscussion Papers717R.

Oinonen, S.,Paloviita, M.,Vilmi, L., 2013. Howhave inflation dynamics changedovertime?EvidencefromtheeuroareaandUSA,BankofFinland ResearchDiscussionPapers6.

Ottaviani,M.,Sørensen,P.N.,2006.Thestrategyofprofessionalforecasting.J. Financ.Econ.81(2),441–466.

Patton,A.,Timmermann,A.,2007.Propertiesofoptimalforecastsunder asym-metriclossandnon-linearity.J.Econometr.140(2),884–918.

Pierdzioch,C.,Stadtmann,G.,Rülke,J.C.,2009.Doprofessionaleconomist’s forecastsreflectOkunslaw?—SomeevidencefortheG7countries.Appl. Econ.43(11),1–9.

Reimers,S.,Harvey,N.,2011.Sensitivitytoautocorrelationinjudgmentaltime seriesforecasting.Int.J.Forecast.27(4),1196–1214.

Rülke, J.C.,2012.Doprofessional forecastersapplythePhillipscurve and Okun’slaw?—EvidencefromsixAsian-Pacificcountries.Jpn.WorldEcon. 24,317–324.

Stark,T.,Croushore,D.,2002.Forecastingwithareal-timedatasetfor macroe-conomists.J.Macroecon.24,507–531.

Tatom,J.A.,1978.Doesthestageofthebusinesscycleaffecttheinflationrate? Rev.FederalReserveBankSt.Louis,7–15.

Tversky,A.,Kahneman,D.,1974.Judgmentunderuncertainty:heuristicsand biases.Science185,1124–1130.

Wallis,K.F.,1989.Macroeconomicforecasting:asurvey.Econ.J.,28–61.

Woodford,M.,2002.Imperfectcommonknowledgeandtheeffectsof mone-tarypolicy.In:Aghion,P.,Frydman,R.,Stiglitz,J.,Woodford,M.(Eds.), Knowledge,InformationandExpectationsinModernMacroeconomics:In HonorofEdmundS.Phelps.PrincetonUniversityPress.

Zarnowitz,V.,Braun,P.,1993.Twenty-twoyearsoftheNBERASA quar-terlyeconomic outlooksurveys:aspectsandcomparisonsofforecasting performance.In:Stock,JamesH.,Watson,MarkW.(Eds.),BusinessCycles, Indicators,andForecasting.TheUniversityofChicagoPress,Chicago,pp. 11–93.

Imagem

Fig. 1. Interquartile range of inflation rate, 1989–2014.
Fig. 2. Distribution of actual and forecasted inflation rate, 1989–2014.
Table 2 Rationality test.
Fig. 4. Descriptive statistics inflation rate forecast errors: consensus 1989–2014.
+2

Referências

Documentos relacionados

Portanto, diante da preocupação com o aumento da prevalência de DCNT e intolerâncias alimentares, o presente estudo objetivou analisar a disponibilidade de alimentos

1 Neste artigo utilizamos a denominação Tecnologias da informação (TI), com base no conceito elaborado por Kyle Eischen (2003). Para a autora, TI refere-se aos

I evaluate the treatment effect of inflation targeting (IT) among industrial economies in the early 1990s, controlling for common time and country specific effects, to show that IT

Ou seja, é nesta fase que as crianças irão aperfeiçoar as habilidades fundamentais gerais como correr, saltar, etc… e as habilidades fundamentais específicas

This paper aimed to determine how efficiently nations from Latin America and Asia measure a country’s performance in converting Economic Complexity into Human Development,

A experiência, à semelhança da vida, vive-se, sem que ocorra, quoti- dianamente, um processo de análise e reflexão consciente do vivido. Re- fletir e falar sobre a experiência exi-

A importância da inclusão educacional em contribuir para a socialização de alunos portadores de necessidade educacionais especiais, a educação Inclusiva favorece a um