• Nenhum resultado encontrado

Two additions to Lucas's "inflation and welfare"

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Share "Two additions to Lucas's "inflation and welfare""

Copied!
13
0
0

Texto

(1)
(2)

Two Additions to Lucas’s "In‡ation and

Welfare"

y

Rubens Penha Cysne

z

April 3, 2004

Abstract

This work adds to Lucas (2000) by providing analytical solutions to two problems that are solved only numerically by the author. The …rst part uses a theorem in control theory (Arrow’s su¢ciency the-orem) to provide su¢ciency conditions to characterize the optimum in a shopping-time problem where the value function need not be concave. In the original paper the optimality of the …rst-order con-dition is characterized only by means of a numerical analysis. The second part of the paper provides a closed-form solution to the general-equilibrium expression of the welfare costs of in‡ation when the money demand is double logarithmic. This closed-form solution allows for the precise calculation of the di¤erence between the general-equilibrium and Bailey’s partial-equilibrium estimates of the welfare losses due to in‡ation. Again, in Lucas’s original paper, the solution to the general-equilibrium-case underlying nonlinear di¤erential equation is done only numerically, and the posterior assertion that the general-equilibrium welfare …gures cannot be distinguished from those derived using Bailey’s formula rely only on numerical simulations as well.

1

Introduction

This work is divided into two independent parts.

This work bene…ted from conversations with Robert E. Lucas Jr. I also thank Paulo Klinger Monteiro and Humberto Moreira for discussing a previous version of the paper. Remaining errors are my responsability. The …rst part of this work paper circulated previously under the title “Su¢cient Conditions for Lucas’s In‡ation and Welfare”.

(3)

The value function derived in Lucas (2000, Section 5) need not be con-cave, leading this author to develop numerical analyses to determine the conditions under which the consumer utility is maximal. The …rst part of the paper uses control methods to derive su¢cient conditions for the prob-lem. Besides substituting for the numerical simulations, a second advantage of using control methods is that it does not require proving the di¤erentia-bility of the value function (which is not done explicitly in the original paper and cannot be performed by standard methods in this nonconcave case) in order to obtain the associated …rst order conditions1.

The second part of the work presents a closed-form solution to Lucas’s general-equilibrium expression for the welfare costs of in‡ation in the double logarithmic case that allows for a direct (analytical) comparison with Bailey’s (1956) partial-equilibrium measure. In the original paper, both the solution of the underlying nonlinear di¤erential equation and the posterior assertion that the general-equilibrium solution cannot be practically distinguished from Bailey’s partial-equilibrium …gures are based only on numerical methods.

2

Su¢cient conditions

The consumer is supposed to maximize utility from the consumption (c) :

Z 1

0

e gt U(c)dt (1)

subject to the households budget constraint (2) and to the transactions-technology constraint (3):

_

m= 1 (c+s) +h m (2)

c+m (s) 0 (3)

In these equations, s stands for the fraction of the initial endowment spent as transacting time (the total endowment of time being equal to the unity), m for the real quantity of money, for the rate of in‡ation,U(c)for a strictly concave utility function; hfor the (exogenous) real value of the ‡ow of money transferred to the household by the government, and g > 0 for a

1On the other hand, the traditional derivation of the Euler equations requires

(4)

discount factor. Following Lucas, in this Section (but not in the next) we particularize the transacting technology by making (s) = ks; k >0:

Since constraint (3) always hold with equality, we use it to substitute for c in the above equations and de…ne the Hamiltonian:

H(m; s; ) =U(kms) + (1 (kms+s) +h m) (4)

It is well known (Mangasarian , (1966)) that the Pontryagin’s (1962) necessary conditions are su¢cient for optimality if the Hamiltonian is jointly concave in the state and control variables. However, this condition is not ful…lled in the present case, due to the term sm in H. However, su¢cient conditions can be generated with the use of Arrow’s (1968) theorem2. In Seierstad and Sydsater’s (1987, p. 107) version, the theorem reads as follows:

Lemma 1 (Arrow’s Su¢ciency Theorem): Let (x(t); u(t)) be a pair that satis…es the conditions (7) and (6) below, in the problem of …nding a piecewise-continuous control vector u(t) and an associated continuously-di¤erentiable state vector variablex(t);de…ned on the time interval[t0; t1], that maximizes:

Z t1

t0

f0(x(t); u(t); t)dt (5)

subject to the di¤erential equations:

_

xi(t) =fi(x(t); u(t); t); i= 1;2; :::; n (6)

and to the conditions

x0i(t0) = x0i , i= 1;2; :::; n (7)

xi(t1) free; i = 1; :::; n

u(t) 2 U Rr:

Given the Hamiltonian function

H(x(t); u(t); p(t); t) =p0f0(x(t); u(t); t) + n

X

i=1

pifi(x; u; t)

2Seidseter and Sydersat (1977) argue (p. 370) that the …rst published demonstration

(5)

if there exists a piecewise continuously-di¤erentiable function p(t) = (p1(t); :::; pn(t))

de…ned on [t0; t1]such that the following conditions are satis…ed with p0 = 1 :

H(x(t); u(t); p(t); t) H(x(t); u(t); p(t); t); for all u2U and all t:(8)

_

pi(t) = Hxi(x(t); u(t); p(t); t); i= 1; :::; n (9)

pi(t1) = 0 i= 1; :::; n (10)

H (x; p(t); t) =max

u2U H(x; u; p; t) exists and is a concave function of x for

all t; then, (x(t); u(t)) solves problem (5)-(7) above.

In this theorem, the concavity of the maximized Hamiltonian with respect to the state variables substitutes for the concavity of the Hamiltonian which is required to hold both for the state and control variables in the theorem due to Mangasarian. Also, notice that this theorem is written for a …nite horizon. As in Lucas (2000), we assume thatlimt!1m(t)=m 2R. It is also assumed that9K >0jU(c(s; m)) K;8(s; m):As pointed out by Seierstad and Sydsater’s (1987, p. 231), in this special case the above theorem can be trivially extended to the in…nite horizon case by reading limt!1pi(t) = 0;

i= 1; :::; nin (10).

In our original problem,s is the control variable (u in the theorem) and m the state variable(x). Relatively to the above theorem, n= 1; U = [0;1]; f0(x; u; t) = U(c); f1(x; u; t) = 1 (kms+s) +h m, [t0; t1] = [0;1]:

Given the way we wrote the Hamiltonian in (4), equation (9) must read

_ (t) +g = Hm(s; m) where, in (10), i = 1 and e gt (t) substitutes for

p1(t):

In order to derive the maximized Hamiltonian used in the theorem, we make the …rst derivative of (4), with respect to the control variable s; equal zero for

U(c) = c1 =(1 ); 6= 1; >0

U(c) = lnc( case = 1)

which corresponds to the utility function used by Lucas. This leads, in both cases above, to:

s = 1

km(

km+ 1

km )

1= (11)

where =U0(c)km=(1 +km)>0:This value of s maximizes the Hamil-tonian, since Hss =U00(c)k2m2 <0:Using (11) in (4), the maximized

(6)

H (m; ) =

1 (

km

(1 +km))

(1 )= + (1 +h m); #1 (12)

H (m; ) = log km

(1 +km)+ (1 1= +h m); (case = 1)

The next step in the application of the theorem is showing that the maxi-mized Hamiltonian is concave with respect to the state variable m: This is trivially satis…ed in the case when = 1 since, given k and ,log (1+kmkm) is a composite function of two monotone increasing concave functions. When

6

= 1; …rst notice that the derivative of (12) with respect tom is given by:

Hm(m; ) = ( km

(1 +km))

(1 )= 1

m(1 +km)

Taking the derivative of the above expression, one easily concludes that Hmm(m; )<0i¤:

> 1

2 + 2km (13)

This expression can be used as a su¢ciency condition. It allows an analytical characterization of the situations in which the absence of concavity is not a problem, adding to the original (numerical) solution. In this caseHis strictly concave in m and the interior balanced path is unique.

Also, since km > 0; a su¢cient condition that does not depend on m is given by

>1=2

As one concludes from (13), lower values of may also implyHmm(m; )<0: To characterize the (unique) stationary point (m; )as an optimum, it re-mains only noticing that the transversality condition (10) (limt!1e gt (t)m(t) =

0 ) is trivially satis…ed under the assumed hypotheses.

(7)

3

A Closed-Form Solution for the Welfare Costs

of In‡ation

The presentations of Lucas’ model in this Section draws on Simonsen and Cysne (2001). As in the …rst Section, the consumer is supposed to maximize (1) subject to (2) and (3).

In the steady-state solution,m converges to a constant …gure, the rate of interest requals the rate of in‡ation plus the discount factor (r= +g);the in‡ation rate equals the rate of monetary expansion and the real transfers (h) equal the in‡ation tax (h = m; standing for the rate of monetary expansion).

In this case, intertemporal optimization leads to the equilibrium equation:

(s) =rm 0

(s) (14)

and equilibrium in the goods market reads:

1 s=m (s) (15)

Solving the system given by (14) and (15) for s = s(r) and m = m(r)

yields implies s0

(r) > 0 and m0

(r) < 0. The problem of deriving s(r) from m(r); without knowing (s) is solved by eliminating (s) and 0

(s) using (14) and (15). The result is the di¤erential equation[Lucas (2000, equation5.8)]:

s0

= r(1 s)

1 s+r m m

0

(16)

which determines the welfare costs(r)as a function of the money-demand m(r).

Lucas (2000) argues that the double-logarithmic functional speci…cation …ts the United States data better than the alternative semi-log speci…cation. Consistently with this observation, we concentrate our analysis by making m(r) =Ar a, 0< a <1; A >0: In this case (16) leads to:

ds

dr = v(r; s) =

(1 s) (aAr a)

1 s+Ar1 a (17)

s(r0) = s0; r0 >0 (18)

(8)

We consider solutions for this equations fors and r in a closed, bounded and convex regionD R2++: Withrbounded away from zero, it is easy to see

thatv(r; s)2C1, and, therefore, by the mean-value theorem, and for a certain

constantL;satis…es the Lipschtz conditionjf(r; s1) f(r; s2)j Ljs1 s2 j

for each par (r; s1);(r; s2)inD: It follows from a standard result in ordinary

di¤erential equations (see, e.g., Coddington and Levinson (1955)) that there exists an interval containing r0 such that a solution to (17) exists, and that

this solution is unique. It is also easy to prove that such a solution can be continued to the right to a maximal interval of existence [r0;+1):

It by no means clear, though, that this non-separable, non-linear di¤eren-tial equation presents a closed-from solution. For example, it is well known that a simple equation like dsdr =w(r; s) =s2 r cannot be expressed as a

…-nite combination of elementary functions or algebraic functions and integrals of such functions. We shall show that such a problem does not happen with (17).

A Closed-Form Solution

Start by considering r0 >0 and the initial condition

s(r0) =s0 (19)

Suppose s(r)is a solution to (17), given (19). Then, since s0

(r0)>0;by the

implicit function theorem, the function r=r(s) inverse tos(r);is de…ned in a su¢ciently small neighborhood of the point s0 and:

dr

ds +

1

a(1 s)r =

1

aAr

a (20)

This type of equation is generally called a Bernoulli equation, which can be easily solved by an adequate change of coordinates.

Consider the di¤eomorphism that associates with each r > 0; t = r1 a:

Then (20) is equivalent to the equation: dt

ds

(1 a)

a(1 s)t=

1 a

aA

Multiplying both sides of this equation by the integration factorexp( R a1(1 as)ds)

and taking into consideration that s(0) = 0 :

t= a 1

A (1 s) +c(1 s)

a 1

a

Sincet=r1 a, we get the general-equilibrium expression for the welfare costs

of in‡ation:

r= a 1

A (1 s)

h

1 (1 s) 1=ai

1 1 a

(9)

4

A Direct Comparison with Bailey’s

Mea-sure

Lucas provides numerical simulations in order to compare his general-equilibrium measure and Bailey’s partial-equilibrium measure (B)of the welfare costs of in‡ation. Having obtained a closed-form solution for the former allows us to provide a direct analytical comparison.

Bailey’s measure is given by the area-under-the-inverse-demand-curve:

dB = rm0

(r)dr; B(0) = 0

By substituting the double-logarithmic money demand function into the above expression and integrating:

r= B(1 a)

aA

1 1 a

(22)

Solving (22) for B and using the value of r given by (21):

B s =a(1 s)( 1 + (1 s) a1) s (23)

Both Lucas (2000), through numerical simulations, and Simonsen and Cysne (2001), analytically, have shown that that Bailey’s measure is an upper bound to Lucas’ general-equilibrium measure, and that the di¤erence between B and s in an increasing function of s. Both conclusions are consistent with equation (23). Indeed, make B(s) s=g(s). Then,g(0) = 0 and

g0

(s) = h(1 s) a1 1

i

(1 a)

Hence, g0(s)>0for anys >0: It follows thatB > sfor any strictly positive values of r: The fact thatB s increases with s follows from the convexity

of g(s).

References

[1] Arrow, K. J. 1968, Applications of control theory to economic growth, in G. B. Dantzig and A. F. Veinott, Jr. eds., Mathematics of the decisions sciences (Providence, R. I. : American Mathematical Society).

(10)

[3] Bailey, Martin J., 1956, Welfare cost of in‡ationary …nance, Journal of Political Economy 64, 93-110.

[4] Coddington, E. A. and N. Levinson, Theory of Ordinary Di¤erential Equations, McGraw Hill, 1955.

[5] Lucas, R. E. Jr., 2000, In‡ation and Welfare. Econometrica 68, No. 62 (March), 247-274.

[6] Mangasarian, O. L., 1966, Su¢cient Conditions for the Optimal Control of Nonlinear Sytems, Siam Journal on Control, IV, February, 139-152.

[7] Pontryagin, L. S.; Boltyanskii, V.; Gamkrelidze, R.; and Mischenko, E. 1962, The mathematical theory of optimal process, New York and London, Interscience.

[8] Seierstad, A. and Sydsaeter K., 1977, Su¢cient Conditions in Optimal Control Theory, International Economic Review, Vol. 18, No2, June.

[9] _________________, 1987, Optimal control theory with eco-nomic applications, North Holland.

(11)

! "! #! $ % $$ &'"

( ) * * ) ! "+,-! ! # # ! $ % .

&'"

/ 0 1 2 1 1 * 1 3 4 ! "+,-! ! #

# ! $ % 5 &'"

. 6* 7 1 * 6 3 8 4 8 1 4 ! "+,-! ! #

# ! $ % % &'"

7 1 2 * 2 9 ) 4 ! "+,-! ! #

# ! $ % $( &'"

3 :* 6

;< 4 =!>! 3-?#! @ ?A ! #! 9 - # !

$ % $ &'"

5 9 ) 9 * 2 3 * 4 ? ! 9 , , @

=! ?A- 2 -" # ! $ % %/ &'"

$ 9 9 * 4

? ! 9 , , @ =! ?A- 2 -" # ! $ % $ &'"

% 1 6 B C 2 ) 22 2

D !, ! !?A ! E # ! $ % 55&'"

1 9 1 :* 1 6 4 74 3 4 - 0A ,

# ! $ % % &'"

2 * 4 * 1 9 9 7 1

9 6 ) 4 ?! 6!,! !@ ! 3- , F A! # ! $ %

$/ &'"

( G * *6 * H 4 ! 1 - #!, 3

IJ!@ , #! 2 9 K = # ! $ % $ &'"

/ 2 * 9* * 2 7 1 * 4 !

F ? ,#- 9 - @ =!>! 3-?#! @ ! # ! $ % .

&'"

. 1 * * 6 2 3 H ,- 2!## - @ 1 #! !

-# ! $ % $ &'"

4 1 *4 * 9 2 4 , #! 2

9 K = # ! $ % %% &'"

5 * * 3 2 * G * 3 3 4

(12)

55 2 * 4 !L -! IJ!@ =! M 9 J ! 6 ?A ,@ -! ' ?!

!F ! $ % %/ &'"

5$ 4 * 1 :* 4

!L -! J!@ 1 #! ! - !F ! $ % %5 &'"

5% :* 6 * ) 0 7 1 ** 9 2 4 J!@ 3 9

#-, !?A @ 0 !,# - ! !F ! $ % 5/ &'"B

5 * 3 0 6 * * ) G 7 9

) 4 !- -! J!@ ' ?- !, !F ! $ % &'"

5 N 2 O P 2 QG 6R 4 , #! 2

9 K = !F ! $ % $/ &'"

5( 3 R3 * 2 G * 4 , #! 2

9 K = !F ! $ % $/ &'"

5/ 3 ; 3 4 9 , , ! 1! ,

6 ! E ! $ % 5/ &'"

5. R S 2 T N 4 ? ! K # M -@

9 - ,! - F 2-!F ,-,- 4 E ! $ % $% &'"

5 1 * 4 ? ! K # M -@ ? ! E 4

E ! $ % $ &'"

$ 7 ) 9 6 O * 2 *

* 4 ? ! K # M - 4 E ! $ % &'"

$5 41 * 1 1 1 7 9 9 9 4 ,

,A U , = , - ! $ 5( &'"

$$ 1 9 ) 0 9* 4 ? !

9 , , @ ! 0 -," !,# - ! 9 F - ! $ $% &'"

$% 1 4 99 6 7 3 2 * 0 4 !L -! J!@

1 #! ! - @ ?! 1 ?A- 9 F - ! $ $5 &'"

$ 3 2 2 H 4 !L -! J!@ 1 #! ! - @ ?! 1

?A- 9 F - ! $ $( &'"

$ 6- , " S ! " ,-E #-!, -",S , -,? ,#-F & !F- -!, 4 - #- ,! ! # @

,-9 - @ 1 #! ! - 9 F - ! $ 55 &'"

$( , # V -, #-, -? , ?!,# V# 4 = - ,! = ,W>!@ 1 #! !

-9 F - ! $ 4 5 &'"

$/ , -? ! ?!-,?- ,# #-F- ?!,K -? ? !,! !"- ? X & !

6 - 4 ," ! = !,#B F , # @ =!>! 3-?#! @ , - & ?!F 4 9 F - !

$ 5 &'"

$. 2 * 6 ) 3 4 OA-J- - !@ -E

(13)

$ 1 0 ) 1 2 * * H )

4 -E , #! - @ OA-J- - ! W! $ $5 &'"

% 7 3 1 1) 1 4 !U! ," 0- @ -E , #! - W!

$ %( &'"

%5 6 O * G 3 9 6 O 4

! F ? ,#- 9 - @ 2-!F ,,- 9 ??A-,- W! $ 4 $ &'"

%$ 2 * H * 9 * 4 ," ! =! M

!,#B F , @ ! F ? ,#- 9 - @ ' ?-! ,#K,-! F #! W! $ $

&'"

%% 9 ;Y G N N9 6 9 , , ! 1! , 6 ! W! $

5( &'"

% N =* Z R 9 , , ! 1! , 6 !

W! $ 5% &'"

% 6 1 2 6 1 99 6 O G 9

3 ) 4 ?! 6!,! !@ 6 #-, #-, @ ! -"! -,#! W! $ %

&'"

%( 1 9 :* 6 9 9 4 * 4 ! 0 -," !,# - ! W!

$ ( &'"

%/ * 7 1 * ) 1 6 ) 9

* 4 ! 0 -," !,# - ! @ 6 , 9 V F -# @ 9 ,[ 1 " = W! $

. &'"

%. :* ) = 64 1 7 1 1 2 *

9 , ,A U , W! $ % &'"

% 9 R 9 9 R 6 G 5 /4$ % 4

, ,A U , @ ! !- 4 - ! W! $ / &'"

1 9 99* F U 4 , ,A

U , - $ $( &'"

5 6* 9 ) * 24 ) 3 4 -E

, #! - @ OA-J- - ! - $ $% &'"

$ ) * * 3 ) 99 * *

- !@ , #! 2 9 K S = @ ?- -! -# - $ $5 &'"

% 7 * \ C 9 7 9 D

4

, ,A U ,

-$ &'"

1 9 6 * )4 ) 3 4

Referências

Documentos relacionados

Because no satisfied ethograms have been found in the literature, this study aims at describing the behavioral patterns of a small group of capuchin monkeys

São apresentados os resultados referentes ao uso dos diferentes métodos de previsão apresentados a valores de diferentes indicadores económicos e financeiros, assim como resultados

No trabalho realizado de dissecação do cahorro-do-mato, podemos observar que do arco aórtico, o primeiro ramo a surgir foi à aorta torácica que se estende pelo lado

Immobilization has long been used to improve enzyme activity and stability in aqueous media, and, more recently, also in nonaqueous media (Bickerstaff, 1997; Bornscheuer, 2003),

In the benchmark speci fi cation, the welfare cost of ten percent instead of zero in fl ation increases from 0.1 percent of income with fi xed periods to one percent with optimal

In Lucas’s (2000) original paper, both the solution of the underlying nonlinear differential equation leading to the general-equilibrium welfare figures, as well as the comparison

Using the data entered, the materials characteristics built in the database system, and the knowledge base on changes in prop- erties due to additional treatment, the

social assistance. The protection of jobs within some enterprises, cooperatives, forms of economical associations, constitute an efficient social policy, totally different from