• Nenhum resultado encontrado

The Strength of the Waterbed Effect Depends on Tariff Type

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2019

Share "The Strength of the Waterbed Effect Depends on Tariff Type"

Copied!
10
0
0

Texto

(1)

The Strength of the

Waterbed Effect

Depends on Tariff

Type

Steffen Hoernig

Working Paper

# 586

(2)

The Strength of the Waterbed E¤ect

Depends on Tari¤ Type

Ste¤en Hoernig

14 May 2014

Abstract

We show that the waterbed e¤ect, i.e. the pass-through of a change in one price of a …rm to its other prices, is much stronger if the latter include subscription rather than only usage fees. In particular, in mobile network competition with a …xed number of customers, the waterbed e¤ect is full under two-part tari¤s, while it is only partial under linear tari¤s.

Keywords: Waterbed e¤ect; two-part tari¤; linear tari¤; mobile termination; two-sided platforms.

JEL: D43, L13, L51

1

Introduction

The "waterbed e¤ect" describes the interdependence between prices at multiple-good …rms and multi-sided platforms. As much as a waterbed rises on one side if it is pressed down on the other, …rms may optimally change prices if some other price is forced to a di¤erent level, for example through regulatory interventions. The extent of the waterbed e¤ect can be a contentious issue when it would weaken the e¤ectiveness of the regulatory measures. In the debate about the downward regulation of the charges paid by …xed networks to mobile networks for routing calls from the former to their receivers on the latter, the so-called "mobile termination rates", mobile networks have claimed that the result would be higher retail prices for mobile customers,

while regulators argued there would be no e¤ect.1

Nova School of Business and Economics, Universidade Nova de Lisboa, Campus de Campolide, 1099-032 Lisboa, Portugal; email: shoernig@novasbe.pt.

1See Schi¤ (2008) for an introduction to the waterbed e¤ect and a discussion of these

(3)

In this note we show how the waterbed e¤ect depends on the type of tari¤ that is charged to the unregulated side of the market. On the regulated side, the …rm receives a …xed payment per customer of the unregulated side. This payment can be the pro…ts from …xed-to-mobile termination of calls, or advertising, or any other pro…ts that depend on the customer’s existence (rather than his usage). We determine the pass-through for two-part tari¤s, where customers pay for subscription and usage, and for linear tari¤s where

they only pay for usage.2 We show that the waterbed e¤ect is much stronger

under two-part than under linear tari¤s; in particular, under the assump-tion of a …xed number of mobile subscribers we show that under two-part tari¤s the waterbed e¤ect is full, while it is only partial with linear tari¤s. This implies that downward regulation of some price leads to a stronger rise negative e¤ect on clients of the other services if the latter are charged a multi-part tari¤. In multi-particular, this result contracts mobile networks’ contention that lower …xed-to-mobile termination rates would disproportionately hurt customers on pre-pay tari¤s.

The issue of the strength of the waterbed e¤ect has been studied in both in theoretical and empirical work. Wright (2002) remains the most important theoretical treatment of …xed-to-mobile interconnection. He shows, generi-cally, that if the pass-through of …xed costs to pro…ts is full (partial), net-works are indi¤erent about termination rates (jointly want to set them at the monopoly level). Below we show that these cases arise due to competition in

two-part or linear tari¤s, respectively.3

Genakos and Valletti (2011a, 2011b) provide an empirical study of the waterbed e¤ect with simultaneous …xed-to-mobile and mobile-to-mobile in-terconnection. They show that the waterbed e¤ect is signi…cantly stronger for post-pay (two-part) than for pre-pay (linear) tari¤s. They ascribe this di¤erence to how the regulation of mobile termination rates a¤ects the inter-connection of calls between mobile networks, and therefore indirectly changes how intensively networks compete for subscribers. While their argument is certainly correct, it is does not take into account that the actual direct pass-through of …xed-to-mobile termination pro…ts depends on the type of tari¤s in the mobile market. In this note, we isolate this factor by considering the two types of termination separately.

2In the market, these types of contract are normally denoted as "post-pay" or "pre-pay

/ pay-as-you-go" tari¤s.

3Armstrong (2002) discusses a model of perfect competition in two-part tari¤s. It

(4)

2

Model Setup

The model setup is a generalization of La¤ont, Rey and Tirole (1998) to many networks and general (instead of Hotelling) subscription demand. We

assume that there are n 2 symmetric mobile networks i = 1; :::; n who

compete in tari¤s. In the main text we consider linear and two-part tari¤s that do not discriminate between calls within the same network (on-net calls) and those to rival networks (o¤-net calls), while in the appendix we analyze tari¤s which price discriminate between these types of calls. Thus for now

we assume that network i charges a price pi for each call minute. In case

networks compete in two-part tari¤s it also charges a …xed fee Fi.

The marginal on-net cost of a call is c >0 and the cost of terminating a

call is c0 >0. Networks charge each other the access charge a per incoming

call minute. Thus the marginal cost of an o¤-net call isc+m, wherem =a c0

is the termination margin. There is a monthly …xed cost f per customer,

and networks receive further monthly pro…ts of Q per customer that do not

originate from payments for retail services o¤ered to them. Our focus will

be on how equilibrium pro…ts depend on Q.

From making a call of length q, a consumer obtains utility u(q), where

u(0) = 0, u0 > 0 and u00 < 0. For call price p, the indirect utility is

v(p) = maxqu(q) pq, call demand is q(p) = v0(p) with elasticity (p) =

pq0(p)=q(p). Receiving a call of length q yields utility u(q), where 0

indicates the strength of the call externality. Lettingvi =v(pi)and assuming

a balanced calling pattern (i.e. subscribers call any other subscriber with the

same probability) the surplus of a consumer on network i is given by

wi =vi+ n

X

j=1

juj Fi;

where Fi is zero for a linear tari¤. The market share of network i= 1; :::; n

is assumed to be

i =A(wi w1; :::; wi wn);

where An : Rn ! R is strictly increasing and symmetric in its arguments,

with 0 i 1, Pni=1 i = 1, from which follows thatA(0; :::;0) = 1=n. Let

= dA(x;0; :::;0)=dxjx=0.4

Denote the pro…ts from a pair of originated and terminated calls between

networksiandj asPij = (pi c m)qi+mqj,i; j = 1; :::; n(access payments

4This demand speci…cation is encapsulates both the generalized Hotelling model of

Hoernig (2014) and the logit model i = exp(wi)=

Pn

j=1exp(wj). We can allow for the

more general speci…cation i=Di(w), but in this case is no longer constant. Expression

(5)

cancel for on-net calls). Network i’s pro…ts are

i = i

n

X

j=1

jPij +Fi f+Q

!

:

3

Equilibrium Pro…ts and the Waterbed

Ef-fect

We will now derive equilibrium pro…ts and determine their dependence on

pro…ts Q, for both linear and two-part tari¤s. As for the latter, network i’s

…rst-order condition for a pro…t maximum is

0 = @ i

@Fi

= i

i

@ i

@Fi

+ i

n

X

j=1

@ j

@Fi

Pij + 1

!

:

In a symmetric Nash equilibrium we have i = 1=n, @ i=@Fi = (n 1) ,

and for allj 6=i,@ j=@Fi = andPij =Pii. Solving the …rst-order condition

for i we obtain

i =

1

(n 1)n2 : (1)

These pro…ts do not depend on Q, i.e. we have a full waterbed e¤ect. As for

linear tari¤s, consider the …rst-order condition for maximizing pro…ts with

respect to the call price pi:

0 = @ i

@pi

= i

i

@ i

@pi

+ i

n

X

j=1

@ j

@pi

Pij + n

X

j=1 j

@Pij

@pi

!

:

In a symmetric Nash equilibrium, we have pi = p and qi = q for all i =

1; :::; n, and thus@ i=@pi = (n 1) q and @ j=@pi = q , with

i =

1 L

(n 1)n2 ; (2)

whereL = (p c (n 1)m=n)=p is the Lerner index for the equilibrium

call price and the corresponding price elasticity of demand. Combining

both expressions for pro…ts shows that even in our more general framework

under two-part tari¤s the call price continues equal to average cost, i.e. L =

0 or p = c+ (n 1)m=n, i.e. does not depend on Q at all. On the other

(6)

combine (2) with the symmetric equilibrium pro…ts i = (P f +Q)=n,

P = (p c)q , to obtain

dp dQ =

(n 1)n

(n 1)n(P )0+ ( L = )0;

where apostrophes denote derivatives with respect to p . Since p is below

the monopoly price (P )0 is strictly positive, and the denominator is

pos-itive unless the demand elasticity decreases very strongly as the call price increases. The following assumption, common in the economic literature,

provides a simple su¢cient condition for ( L )0 >0.

Assumption 1: The price elasticity of demand (:)is non-decreasing.

Under this assumption, we conclude that under linear tari¤s higher Q

feeds through to lower call prices, dp =dQ <0. Finally, we obtain

d(n i)

dQ =

( L = )0

(n 1)n(P )0+ ( L = )0; (3)

which implies that only by chance the waterbed e¤ect is full (d(n i)=dQ=

0). Under Assumption 1, we obtain 0 < d(n i)=dQ < 1, i.e. higher Q is

translated into higher industry pro…ts, but only partially so.5

Summing up:

Proposition 1 In symmetric equilibrium, the waterbed e¤ect is

1. full under two-part tari¤s;

2. partial under linear tari¤s.

As shown in the Appendix, much the same results hold if networks price discriminate between on- and o¤-net calls, as originally discussed in Hoernig (2010).

Two conclusions follow from these results: First, in general terms the exact structure of tari¤s on one side of a market dictates how price changes on some other side are transmitted, even though di¤erent groups of customers are involved. Thus the design of regulation must take types of tari¤s in unregulated market segments into account. Second, for the speci…c case of regulation of …xed-to-mobile termination charges, our results show that concerns about reduced consumer welfare due to the waterbed e¤ect are less justi…ed for consumers on pre-pay (linear) tari¤s than those on post-pay (two-part) tari¤s, contrary to what networks have often publicly claimed.

5If Assumption 1 were to be strongly violated then industry pro…t would even decrease

(7)

References

[1] Armstrong, Mark, 2002. "The theory of access pricing and interconnec-tion," in Cave, M., Majumdar, S., Vogelsang, I., (Eds.), Handbook of Telecommunications Economics. North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[2] Genakos, Christos and Tommaso Valletti, 2011a. "Testing The “Wa-terbed” E¤ect In Mobile Telephony," Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(6), 1114-1142.

[3] Genakos, Christos and Valletti, Tommaso, 2011. "Seesaw in the air: In-terconnection regulation and the structure of mobile tari¤s," Information Economics and Policy, 23(2), 159-170.

[4] Hoernig, Ste¤en, 2010. "Competition Between Multiple Asymmetric Net-works: Theory and Applications," CEPR Discussion Paper 8060.

[5] Hoernig, Ste¤en, 2014. "Competition Between Multiple Asymmetric Net-works: Theory and Applications," International Journal of Industrial Or-ganization, 32(1), 57-69.

[6] La¤ont, Jean-Jacques, Patrick Rey and Jean Tirole, 1998. "Network Competition: I. Overview and Nondiscriminatory Pricing," RAND Jour-nal of Economics, 29(1), 1-37.

[7] Schi¤, Aaron, 2008. "The “Waterbed” E¤ect and Price Regulation," Re-view of Network Economics, 7(3), 392-414.

[8] Wright, Julian, 2002. "Access Pricing under Competition: An Applica-tion to Cellular Networks," Journal of Industrial Economics, 50(3), 289-315.

4

Appendix: Destination-Based Price

Discrim-ination

As in Hoernig (2010), we assume that network i charges a per-minute price

pi for calls within the same network (on-net calls) and a per-minute price

^

pi for calls to the other mobile network (o¤-net calls). Thus either networks

charge multi-part tari¤s(Fi; pi;p^i)or linear tari¤s(pi;p^i). Lettingvi =v(pi),

^

(8)

any other subscriber with the same probability) the surplus of a consumer

on network iis given by

wi = i(vi+ ui) +

X

j6=i

j(^vi+ ^uj) Fi = n

X

j=1

jhij Fi;

where hii = vi + ui and hij = ^vi+ ^uj for j 6= i, and Fi is equal to zero

under a linear tari¤.

Denote the pro…ts from one on-net call as Pii = (pii c)qii and those of

a pair of outgoing and incoming o¤-net calls as Pij = (^pi c m)^qi +mq^j,

j 6=i. Network i’s pro…ts are

i = i

n

X

j=1

jPij +Fi f+Q

!

:

Letting h be the n n-matrix of hij, and w and F then 1-vectors of wi

and Fi, we can write w= h F. Write market shares as i =Di(w) and

= D(h F) for a function D : Rn ! Rn with Jacobian W, then we

obtain the market share derivatives

d

dF = W h d

dF I () d

dF = G d

dp = W h d dp +

dh

dp () d

dp =G dh dp ;

where I is the identity matrix and G = (I W h) 1W, with elements Gij,

i; j = 1; :::; n. For the derivatives with respect to …xed fees, we obtain

d j

dFi

= Gji:

As for call prices, note …rst thatdh=dpiis ann n-matrix with entrydhii=pi =

qi+ u0(pi)qi0 = qi(1 + i)at position(i; i)and zeros otherwise; similarly,

forj 6=ithe matrixdh=dp^ihas entriesdhij=dp^i = q^ianddhji=dp^i = q^i ^i,

and is otherwise equal to zero. As a result, we have, for j = 1; :::; n,

d j

dpi

= qi(1 + i) iGji;

d j

dp^i

= q^i Gji(1 i) + ^i i

X

k6=i

Gjk

!

:

Since market shares sum to 1, we have Wii+

P

j6=iWij = 0 for all i. This

implies Pk6=iGjk = Gji,

6 and thus

d j

dp^i

= ^qiGji((1 + ^i) i 1):

(9)

In a symmetric equilibrium, Wij = for all i and j 6= i, and thus Wii =

(n 1) . Furthermore, in symmetric equilibrium all hii hon are identical,

and so are all hij hof, for j 6=i. After some computations, we …nd

Gii=Gon

(n 1)

1 n(hon hof)

; Gij =Gof

1 n(hon hof)

; 8j 6=i;

First we determine the equilibrium pro…ts under multi-part tari¤s, follow-ing Hoernig (2014): The …rst-order condition for pro…t-maximization with respect to …xed fees is

0 = @ i

@Fi

= d i

dFi i i + i n X j=1 d j dFi

Pij + 1

!

;

which can be solved for the symmetric equilibrium pro…ts ( i = 1=n, Pii =

Pmp

on , Pij =Pofmp),

mp i = 2 i n X j=1 Gji Gii Pij 1 Gii ! = 1 n2 1

(n 1) +

n(hof hon)

n 1 +P mp

of P

mp

on :

As is known (e.g. Hoernig 2014),7 under multi-part tari¤s with price

dis-crimination between on- and o¤-net calls the equilibrium call prices are

pmp = c=(1 + ) and p^mp = (c+m)=(1 =(n 1)). Call prices and h on,

hof,PofmpandPonmpdo not depend onQ. As a result, equilibrium pro…ts under

multi-part tari¤s are independent of Q, and the waterbed e¤ect is full.

As for linear tari¤s, the …rst-order condition for the pro…t-maximizing on-net price at the symmetric equilibrium is

0 = @ i

@pi

= d i

dpi i i + i n X j=1 d j dpi

Pij + i

dPii

dpi

!

;

with pro…ts under linear tari¤s of

lt on = 2 i n X j=1 Gji Gii Pij 1 (1 + i)Gii

1 pi c

pi i

!

= 1

n2 Pof Pon+

1 n(hon hof)

(n 1)

1 Lon

1 +

7This result can be derived from using the above …rst-order condition with respect to

(10)

and on-net Lerner index Lon = (p c)=p. Equally, by using the …rst-order condition for the pro…t-maximizing o¤-net price we obtain

0 = @ i

@p^i

= d i

dp^i i

i

+ i

n

X

j=1

d j

dp^i

Pij +

X

j6=i j

dPij

dp^i

!

;

or, with Lof = (^p c m)=p^,

lt

of =

2 i

n

X

j=1

Gji

Gii

Pij +

X

j6=i

j

((1 + ^i) i 1)Gii

1 p^i c m

^

pi ^i

!

= 1

n2 Pof Pon+

1 n(hon hof) 1 ^Lof

n 1 ^ :

Equating lt

on to ltof, we obtain

1 Lon

1 + =

(n 1) (1 ^Lof)

n 1 ^ :

This result implies that the Lerner indices tendLon and Lof tend to move in

lockstep, that is, if higherQleads to a lower on-net price then the o¤-net price

will decrease as well. While the exact comparative statics are too involved

to be discussed here, this implies that changes in Q are not compensated by

opposing shifts in on- and o¤-net call prices.

If call externalities and access margins are small ( ; m 0), then the

equilibrium condition implies p^ p, and similar computations as in the

main text lead to

d n lt

dQ

( Lon= )

0

(n 1)nP0

on+ ( Lon= )0

;

Referências

Documentos relacionados

For examining the discourses of citizens and representatives of expert-political systems regarding public participation within processes of participatory budgeting, we selected

O trabalho artístico realizado em contextos prisionais - os atores sociais em interação sobre o seu território (a instituição total) - as relações entre os grupos de reclusos e

Nota: No exemplo, clarifica o tipo de experiência afetiva, a intensidade da experiência afetiva, a duração da experiência afetiva (p.ex. quantas vezes o

The probability of attending school four our group of interest in this region increased by 6.5 percentage points after the expansion of the Bolsa Família program in 2007 and

It is an important factor in determining the well-being and adaptive functioning of human beings (Cicchetti, Ackerman, &amp; Izard, 1995), preventing high levels of stress

The objective of this study was to model, analyze and compare the structure of spatial dependence, as well as the spatial variability of the water depths applied by a

Trabalho de Conclusão de Curso apresentado ao Curso de Formação de Gestores Culturais dos Estados do Nordeste, promovido pelo Instituto de Humanidades, Artes e Ciências

The success of a greedy routing scheme depends on the type of network to which it is ap- plied. On paper [6] it is studied the suitability of a special type of networks: