• Nenhum resultado encontrado

A note on the integrability of partial-equilibrium measures of the welfare costs of inflation

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2020

Share "A note on the integrability of partial-equilibrium measures of the welfare costs of inflation"

Copied!
7
0
0

Texto

(1)

A note on the integrability of

partial-equilibrium measures of the welfare

costs of inflation

q

Rubens Penha Cysne

1

Fundacß~aao Getulio Vargas, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil Received 19 January 2001; accepted 6 June 2001

Abstract

Multidimensional measures of the welfare costs of inflation have been employed in the literature without an explicit concern of how the demand for the respective mone-tary assets are generated and without an investigation of the respective integrability con-ditions. This note establishes conditions under which such welfare measures are well defined.

Ó 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

JEL classification: E40; E60

Keywords: Inflation; Welfare; Integrability

1. Introduction

This work investigates the integrability of multidimensional partial-equilibrium measures of the welfare costs of inflation. Such measures, which in a certain way

www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase

q

A previous version of this paper circulated with the title ‘‘Integrability and the demand for monetary assets: an alternative approach to an old problem’’.

E-mail address:rpcysne@midway.uchicago.edu(R.P. Cysne).

1Rubens Penha Cysne is a professor of economics at the Fundacß~aao Getulio Vargas (FGV) and a

researcher at the IBRE/FGV.

0378-4266/02/$ - see front matterÓ 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S 0 3 7 8 - 4 26 6 ( 0 1 ) 0 0 21 3 - 8

(2)

extend Bailey’s (1956) seminal contribution, are particularly aimed at economies where more than one asset perform monetary functions. They have been used in the literature (Marty and Chaloupka, 1988; Marty, 1994, 1999; Baltensperger and Jordan, 1997), though, without an explicit concern about the issue of path indepen-dence, as well as the issue of how the demands for the respective monetary assets are derived. By showing how this can be done and under what conditions these measures are well defined, their applicability is strengthened.

This is even more important due to the fact that, elsewhere, Lucas (2000), for the one-dimensional case, as well as Simonsen and Cysne (2001) and Cysne (2001), for the n-dimensional case, have shown that such partial-equilibrium measures can be regarded as very good approximations, especially for moderate rates of inflation, of their general-equilibrium counterparts.

Our procedure can be understood as paralleling the search, in classical static con-sumer theory, of particular specifications of the utility function which assured the in-tegrability of Marshallian demands (the two classic textbook cases being those of homothetic preferences and of parallel preferences with respect to the numeraire). Likewise, we look for conditions that a certain transacting technology must fulfill in order to make a specific welfare measure well defined.

Our basic conclusion is that, in a shopping-time framework, the partial-equilib-rium measure of the welfare costs of inflation is well defined (path independent) if and only if the transacting technology is blockwise-weakly separable with respect to the monetary variables and shopping time. Expressed differently, the marginal rates of substitution between the two monetary assets must be independent of the total shopping time.

Our derivation of the demands for the monetary assets is based on Simonsen and Cysne (2001) model, which, in turn, draws on Lucas (1993, 2000) previous analysis of welfare costs of inflation in shopping-time economies. To simplify, we present a model using currency and one kind of alternative monetary asset, which we call de-posits. Our basic results, though, can be easily extended to the case when more than two assets perform monetary functions.

This note presents two more sections. Section 2develops the basic model. Section 3 presents the partial-equilibrium measure of the welfare costs of inflation, establishes conditions for its path independence and displays two contrasting exam-ples.

2. The model

This section draws heavily on the exposition of the model in Simonsen and Cysne (2001). Households are assumed to maximize discounted utility subject to their bud-get constraint and to the constraint that the total time spent producing the consump-tion good and shopping must sum to one. A transacting technology specifies how currency and deposits permit agents to economize on the amount of time spent on transactions in the goods market.

(3)

Household preferences are determined by Z 1

0

egtUðcÞ dt ð1Þ

where U : X0! R, X0 Rþ, is a strictly concave function of the consumption

at instant t and g > 0. The household is endowed with one unit of time that can be used to transact or to produce the consumption good with constant returns to scale:

yþ s ¼ 1: ð2Þ

Here, y stands for the production of the consumption good and s for the fraction of the initial endowment spent as transacting time. Households can accumulate three assets: currency ðMÞ, bonds ðBÞ and deposits ðX Þ.

In their maximization, households take as given the nominal interest rate of bonds, i, and the opportunity cost of holding deposits, j¼ i  ix, where ixis the

in-terest rate paid by X and 0 < j < i. Letting P ¼ P ðtÞ be the price of the consumption good, the household faces the budget constraint

_ M

Mþ _BBþ _XX ¼ iB þ ixX þ P yð  cÞ þ H :

H indicates the flow of currency transferred to the household by the government and the dot over the variable its time derivative. Making a ¼ ðM þ B þ X Þ=P , p ¼ _PP =P (inflation rate), m¼ M=P , x ¼ X =P and h ¼ H =P , and taking Eq. (2) into account, the budget constraint reads

_a

a¼ ið  pÞa þ 1  s  im  jx  c þ h: ð3Þ Compared to currency, or to deposits, bonds are obviously preferable as a reserve of value. However, currency, as well as deposits, are useful because they save trans-action time, as the transacting function describes:

c¼ F ðm; x; sÞ: ð4Þ

F is supposed to be differentiable and strictly increasing in each of its variables, with decreasing marginal returns.

The household maximizes Eq. (1) subject to the budget constraint (3) and subject to the time-transacting technology (4).

The steady state is characterized by _mm¼ _bb¼ _xx ¼ 0. Also, in steady state, the rate of inflation is determined so that the seigniorage matches the real value of the net transfers made by the government (h¼ pm, where p ¼ _MM =M).

In steady state, Euler’s equations lead to the equilibrium relations: i¼ p þ g;

Fm¼ iFs; ð5Þ

(4)

In equilibrium, since the consumption good is non-storable and since all house-holds are equal, y¼ c. Using Eqs. (2) and (4), we get the fourth equation that com-pletes the model:

1 s ¼ F ðm; x; sÞ: ð7Þ

We use Eqs. (5)–(7) to determine, locally, i, j and s, as functions of m and x. In this model, the shopping-time variableðsÞ can be considered as a general-equi-librium measure of the welfare costs of inflation (Simonsen and Cysne, 2001; Lucas, 2000). Indeed, since fiat money can be produced with a zero social cost, the totality of the transacting services demanded in the economy could be produced at no cost. Time dedicated to shopping is therefore a waste.

In what follows, though, we will be solely interested in the partial-equilibrium measure of the welfare costs of inflation PE, to be defined in the next section. Simon-sen and Cysne (2001) show, in the particular case when j is constant, that PEðBðiBÞ

in their paperÞ is an upper bound to s. Cysne (2001) extends this result, under certain conditions on the path followed by the parameters of the model, by relaxing the as-sumption of a constant value of j.

3. Integrability

We will be interested in the evaluation of iðm; xÞ and jðm; xÞ along paths CðtÞ ¼ ðmðtÞ, xðtÞÞ, CðtÞ  V , V an open set of R2

þþ and a 6 t 6 b. With currency and

interest-bearing deposits, the partial-equilibrium measure of the welfare costs of in-flation is given by the line integral

PE¼  Z

C

Kdr ð8Þ

where K¼ ðiðm; xÞ; jðm; xÞÞ and dr ¼ ðdm; dxÞ. PE can be interpreted as a general-ization of the area under a demand curve, although it is a different object from the mathematical point of view.

For PE to be well defined as a welfare measure, it must take a unique value for different paths of m and x, when the initial and final points are the same (path inde-pendence). It is a well-known result from Calculus, sometimes referred to as the ‘‘po-tential function theorem’’ (see e.g. Apostol, 1957; Lang, 1987), that such path independence happens iff K is the gradient of some function b in all points where K is defined. Locally, this is equivalent to having:

oi

oxðm; xÞ ¼ oj

omðm; xÞ ð9Þ

in all points of V.

The formal definition and an encompassing analysis of separability can be found in Leontief (1947). For our purposes, the function Fðm; x; sÞ is said to be blockwise-weakly separable when there are functions G and H such that Fðm; x; sÞ ¼

(5)

HðGðm; xÞ; sÞ. It also follows from the analysis made by Leontief that this condition is equivalent to having the marginal rate of substitution between m and x indepen-dent of s:

o

osðFm=FxÞ ¼ 0:

The following proposition uses this definition to establish our main result:

Proposition 1. The welfare measure PE is well defined (path independent) if and only if the transacting technology Fðm; x; sÞ is blockwise-weakly separable with respect to the monetary aggregator and the shopping-time variable, s.

Proof. Considering Eq. (4) and the equilibrium conditions, taking the partial de-rivatives of Eqs. (5)–(7) and making

D¼ det Fs 0 iFss Fms 0 Fs jFss Fxs 0 0 1þ Fs 2 4 3 5 ¼ F2 sð1 þ FsÞ > 0: We have Doi ox ¼ Fs½ðiFsx FmxÞð1 þ FsÞ  iFð ss FmsÞFx; Doj om ¼ Fs½ðjFsm FxmÞð1 þ FsÞ  ðjFss FxsÞFm: Therefore, Fsð1 þ FsÞ oi ox   oj om  ¼ ðiFsxþ jFsmÞð1 þ FsÞ þ FssðiFx jFmÞ þ ðFmFxs FxFmsÞ:

Substituting Fm=Fsand Fx=Fs, respectively, for i and j, in the above expression, one

concludes that oi=ox¼ oj=om for any values of m and x if and only if FmsFx¼

FmFxs() oðFm=FxÞ=os ¼ 0. 

Example 1. Consider an economy with transacting technology: Fðm; x; sÞ ¼ Aðm1=2þ sÞx1=2; A >

0:

This technology is not weakly separable, since Fm=Fx6¼ Fms=Fxs. Given the first order

(6)

iðm; xÞ ¼ 1 2m1=2;

jðx; mÞ ¼ 1þ m

1=2

2xð1 þ Ax1=2Þ;

and the partial-equilibrium welfare measure PE¼  Z C 1 2m1=2dmþ 1þ m1=2 2xð1 þ Ax1=2Þdx: ð10Þ

Since in this example we are interested only in comparing the values of PE along different paths, we make A¼ 1 to simplify the calculations. Let us then suppose that this economy presents an initial value ofðm; xÞ given by ð0:04; 0:04Þ, and a final value ofð0:01; 0:01Þ. We consider two different paths. In the first, C1, the economy moves

fromð0:04; 0:04Þ to ð0:01; 0:01Þ along the straight line x ¼ m ¼ t. The second path is a union of two intermediate paths. In the first, C21, in which m is always kept

constant, the economy moves fromð0:04; 0:04Þ to ð0:04; 0:01Þ. In the second, C22, in

which x is always kept constant in its new level, 0:01, the economy moves from ð0:04; 0:01Þ to ð0:01; 0:01Þ. By first calculating the value of PE for C1, making

x¼ m ¼ t and dx ¼ dm ¼ dt in Eq. (10), we get PE1¼ 0:1 þ log 2. On the other

hand, along C22, PE22¼ 0:1, whereas along C21we have

PE21¼ 0:6

Z 0:04 0:01

1

xð1 þ x1=2Þdx:

Since PE2¼ PE21þ PE22, PE1¼ PE2() PE21¼ ln 2. However, this does not occur,

as the inequality below shows: PE21¼ 0:6 Z 0:04 0:01 1 xð1 þ x1=2Þdx > 0:6 Z 0:04 0:01 1 1:2xdx¼ 0:5 Z 0:04 0:01 1 xdx ¼ log 2:

Any evaluation of PE for this economy would therefore have to consider the path followed by the variables.

Example 2. Here we consider the technology Fðm; x; sÞ ¼ Gðm; xÞs ¼ Bmax1as,

B >0. This technology is separable, since Fm=Fx ¼ Fms=Fxs¼ ða=ð1  aÞÞðx=mÞ.

Along a path C, this technology leads to the following measure of PE: PE¼  Z C a m 1 Bmax1aþ 1dmþ 1 a x 1 Bmax1aþ 1dx: ð11Þ

We prove path independence by showing that this problem admits a potential function. By making Gðm; xÞ ¼ Bmax1aand solving the partial differential equations

(7)

oCðm; xÞ om ¼ a m 1 1þ G; oCðm; xÞ ox ¼ 1 a x 1 1þ G:

One easily finds the potential function to be Cðm; xÞ ¼ logðG=ð1 þ GÞÞ. Hence, for initial and final values of m and x given by, respectively, mð 1; x1Þ and ðm2; x2Þ:

PE¼ ðCðm2; x2Þ  C mð 1; x1ÞÞ

whatever the path taken byðm; xÞ between these two points.

Acknowledgements

This work benefitted from conversations with Robert Lucas Jr. Humberto More-ira, Paulo Klinger Monteiro, Samuel Pessoa and two anonymous referees made valuable comments and suggestions. Remaining errors are my responsibility. The work was carried out while I was visiting the Department of Economics of the Uni-versity of Chicago. I wish to thank the Department for its hospitality and the finan-cial support from Capes.

References

Apostol, T., 1957. Mathematical Analysis. Addison Wesley, Reading, MA.

Bailey, M.J., 1956. Welfare cost of inflationary finance. Journal of Political Economy 64, 93–110. Baltensperger, E., Jordan, T.J., 1997. Seigniorage, banking, and the optimal quantity of money. Journal of

Banking and Finance 21, 781–796.

Cysne, R., 2001. Divisia indexes, inflation and welfare. Working paper 397, FGV, and the University of Chicago. Annals of the 2001, Summer Meeting of the North American Econometric Society. Lang, S., 1987. Calculus of Several Variables, third ed. Springer, Berlin.

Leontief, W., 1947. Introduction to a theory of the internal structure of functional relationships. Econometrica 15 (4), 361–373.

Lucas Jr., R.E., 1993. The welfare costs of inflation. Working paper. University of Chicago, Chicago. Lucas Jr., R.E., 2000. Inflation and welfare. Econometrica 68, 247–274.

Marty, A.L., 1994. The inflation tax and the marginal welfare cost in a world of currency and deposits. The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 76, 67–71.

Marty, A.L., 1999. The welfare cost of inflation: A critique of Bailey and Lucas. Federal Bank of St. Louis Review, No. 1.

Marty, A.L., Chaloupka, F., 1988. Optimal inflation rates: A generalization. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 20, 141–144.

Simonsen, M.H., Cysne, R.P., 2001. Welfare costs of inflation and interest-bearing deposits. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 33-1, 90–101.

Referências

Documentos relacionados

São apresentados os resultados referentes ao uso dos diferentes métodos de previsão apresentados a valores de diferentes indicadores económicos e financeiros, assim como resultados

A Figura 20 apresenta o comportamento da porosidade dos corpos-de-prova cerâmicos, em função do resíduo de granito nas temperaturas de sinterização estudadas.. Figura 20 –

• Generally speaking, Portugal pays a premium above German interest rates, but that premium is unstable from one day to the next, and tends to increase with time to maturity of

In the benchmark speci fi cation, the welfare cost of ten percent instead of zero in fl ation increases from 0.1 percent of income with fi xed periods to one percent with optimal

[r]

The probability of attending school four our group of interest in this region increased by 6.5 percentage points after the expansion of the Bolsa Família program in 2007 and

Ousasse apontar algumas hipóteses para a solução desse problema público a partir do exposto dos autores usados como base para fundamentação teórica, da análise dos dados

No trabalho realizado de dissecação do cahorro-do-mato, podemos observar que do arco aórtico, o primeiro ramo a surgir foi à aorta torácica que se estende pelo lado