• Nenhum resultado encontrado

Common cycles and the importance of transitory shocks to macroeconomic aggregates (revised version)

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Share "Common cycles and the importance of transitory shocks to macroeconomic aggregates (revised version)"

Copied!
36
0
0

Texto

(1)

❊♥s❛✐♦s ❊❝♦♥ô♠✐❝♦s

❊s❝♦❧❛ ❞❡

Pós✲●r❛❞✉❛çã♦

❡♠ ❊❝♦♥♦♠✐❛

❞❛ ❋✉♥❞❛çã♦

●❡t✉❧✐♦ ❱❛r❣❛s

◆◦ ✸✸✺ ■❙❙◆ ✵✶✵✹✲✽✾✶✵

❈♦♠♠♦♥ ❈②❝❧❡s ❛♥❞ t❤❡ ■♠♣♦rt❛♥❝❡ ♦❢ ❚r❛♥✲

s✐t♦r② ❙❤♦❝❦s t♦ ▼❛❝r♦❡❝♦♥♦♠✐❝ ❆❣❣r❡❣❛t❡s

✭❘❡✈✐s❡❞ ❱❡rs✐♦♥✮

❋❛rs❤✐❞ ❱❛❤✐❞✱ ❏♦ã♦ ❱✐❝t♦r ■ss❧❡r

(2)

❖s ❛rt✐❣♦s ♣✉❜❧✐❝❛❞♦s sã♦ ❞❡ ✐♥t❡✐r❛ r❡s♣♦♥s❛❜✐❧✐❞❛❞❡ ❞❡ s❡✉s ❛✉t♦r❡s✳ ❆s

♦♣✐♥✐õ❡s ♥❡❧❡s ❡♠✐t✐❞❛s ♥ã♦ ❡①♣r✐♠❡♠✱ ♥❡❝❡ss❛r✐❛♠❡♥t❡✱ ♦ ♣♦♥t♦ ❞❡ ✈✐st❛ ❞❛

❋✉♥❞❛çã♦ ●❡t✉❧✐♦ ❱❛r❣❛s✳

❊❙❈❖▲❆ ❉❊ PÓ❙✲●❘❆❉❯❆➬➹❖ ❊▼ ❊❈❖◆❖▼■❆ ❉✐r❡t♦r ●❡r❛❧✿ ❘❡♥❛t♦ ❋r❛❣❡❧❧✐ ❈❛r❞♦s♦

❉✐r❡t♦r ❞❡ ❊♥s✐♥♦✿ ▲✉✐s ❍❡♥r✐q✉❡ ❇❡rt♦❧✐♥♦ ❇r❛✐❞♦ ❉✐r❡t♦r ❞❡ P❡sq✉✐s❛✿ ❏♦ã♦ ❱✐❝t♦r ■ss❧❡r

❉✐r❡t♦r ❞❡ P✉❜❧✐❝❛çõ❡s ❈✐❡♥tí✜❝❛s✿ ❘✐❝❛r❞♦ ❞❡ ❖❧✐✈❡✐r❛ ❈❛✈❛❧❝❛♥t✐

❱❛❤✐❞✱ ❋❛rs❤✐❞

❈♦♠♠♦♥ ❈②❝❧❡s ❛♥❞ t❤❡ ■♠♣♦rt❛♥❝❡ ♦❢ ❚r❛♥s✐t♦r② ❙❤♦❝❦s t♦ ▼❛❝r♦❡❝♦♥♦♠✐❝ ❆❣❣r❡❣❛t❡s ✭❘❡✈✐s❡❞ ❱❡rs✐♦♥✮✴ ❋❛rs❤✐❞ ❱❛❤✐❞✱ ❏♦ã♦ ❱✐❝t♦r ■ss❧❡r ✕ ❘✐♦ ❞❡ ❏❛♥❡✐r♦ ✿ ❋●❱✱❊P●❊✱ ✷✵✶✵

✭❊♥s❛✐♦s ❊❝♦♥ô♠✐❝♦s❀ ✸✸✺✮ ■♥❝❧✉✐ ❜✐❜❧✐♦❣r❛❢✐❛✳

(3)

Common Cycles and the Import ance of

Transitory Shocks t o Macroeconomic Aggregates

¤

Jo~

ao Vict or Issler

Graduat e School of Economics - EPGE

Get ulio Vargas Foundat ion

Praia de Bot afogo 190 s. 1125

Rio de Janeiro, RJ 22253-900, Brazil

jissler@fgv.br

Farshid Vahid

Texas A& M University

Depart ment of Economics

College Station, T X 77843-4228, USA

fv@econ4.t amu.edu

T his version: Sept ember 1998

A bst r act

Alt hough t here has been subst ant ial research using long-run co-movement (coint egrat ion) rest rict ions in t he empirical macroeconomics lit erat ure, lit -t le or no work has been done inves-t iga-t ing -the exis-t ence of shor-t -run co-movement (common cycles) rest rictions and discussing t heir implicat ions.

¤We grat efully acknowledge comment s from Heat her Anderson, Wout er den Haan, Robert

(4)

In this paper we ¯ rst invest igat e the existence of common cycles in a aggre-gate data set comprising per-capit a out put , consumption, and invest ment. Lat er we discuss their usefulness in measuring t he relat ive import ance of t ransit ory shocks. We show that , t aking int o account common-cycle re-st rict ions, t ransit ory shocks are more important than previously thought at business-cycle horizons. T he cent ral argument relies on e± ciency gains from imposing these short -run rest rict ions on the est imat ion of t he dynamic model. Finally, we discuss how t he evidence here and elsewhere can be in-t erprein-t ed in-to supporin-t in-t he view in-thain-t nominal shocks may be imporin-t anin-t in in-the short run.

1. I nt r oduct i on

It is a well known stylized fact in macroeconomics t hat economic dat a display co-movement . For example, Lucas(1977, sect ion 2) report s t hat out put co-movement s across broadly de¯ ned sect ors have high coherence. On t he ot her hand, K osobud and K lein(1961) document t hat aggregat e consumpt ion, invest ment and out put follow balanced growt h pat hs. While t he ¯ rst observat ion is a st at ement about short -run co-movement , which imposes rest rict ions on t ransit ional dynamics of sect oral out put s, t he second is a st at ement about long-run co-movement , impos-ing t he rest rict ion t hat macroeconomic aggregat es cannot drift apart over t ime. T hese two types of rest rict ions play an import ant role in det ermining t he dynamic behavior of macroeconomic t ime series.

(5)

Gal¶i(1996), who uses long-run rest rict ions t o ident ify \ product ivity" shocks and examine how t he predict ions of a class of Real-Business-Cycle models ¯ t t he dat a. Alt hough t he use of low-frequency (coint egrat ion) rest rict ions t o decompose economic series int o t rends and cycles is widely used, t his is by no means t he only type of rest rict ions t hat can be employed t o t hat end. High-frequency rest rict ions (common cycles) can also be used in conjunct ion wit h coint egrat ion rest rict ions, whenever t he lat t er exist . T his was init ially shown by Vahid and Engle(1993), who proposed t he use of t hecommon trends and common cycles met hod, lat er applied t o a sect oral out put dat a set by Engle and Issler(1995); see also Engle and K ozicki(1993) for a broader view of t hese \ common feat ures."

For a given dat a set , t he joint use of common-t rend and common-cycle re-st rict ions t o ident ify permanent and t ransit ory shocks has a clear advant age over t he use of common-t rend rest rict ions alone. First , t here is t he econometric is-sue of relat ive e± ciency. Obviously, if common-cycle rest rict ions are correct ly imposed, est imates of t he dynamic model (usually a Vect or Aut oregression) are more precise, leading t o a more precise measurement of t he relative import ance of permanent and t ransit ory shocks. Indeed, if two series have a common cycle t heir impulse-response funct ions are exact ly colinear (Vahid and Engle(1997)). T hus, variance-decomposit ion and impulse-response calculat ions will be based on a re-duced set of paramet ers. Second, t here is t he issue of t he horizon when measuring t he relat ive import ance of shocks. For bot h met hods, t he relat ive import ance of permanent and t ransit ory shocks should not di®er much for long horizons, since bot h impose t he same long-run rest rict ions. However, t hey have t he pot ent ial t o be di®erent for short horizons, because rest rict ions on short -run dynamics are imposed by only one of t hem.

(6)

T he goal of t his paper is t o examine whet her U.S. per-capit a out put , consump-t ion, and invesconsump-t menconsump-t share common cycles using consump-t hecommon trends and common cycles met hod discussed in Vahid and Engle(1993). T here, long-run co-movement is charact erized as common st ochastic t rends and short -run co-movement is char-act erized as common cyclical component s t hat are synchronized in phase but may have di®erent amplit udes. Using e± cient est imat es of a vect or aut oregres-sive model which is rest rict ed t o produce common t rends and common cycles, we calculat e t he relat ive import ance of permanent and t ransit ory shocks. We lat er con¯ rm t he e± ciency gains for our dat a set in an out -of-sample forecast ing exercise.

Invest igat ing t he exist ence of common cycles is int erest ing in it s own right , given t hat t his is a t heoret ical implicat ion of several dynamic macroeconomic mod-els. Examples of t hese models are provided below. Using a more e± cient t rend-cycledecomposit ion of t hedat a weareable t o answer more precisely a key quest ion in macroeconomics, considered, among ot hers, by Nelson and Plosser(1982), Wat -son(1986), Campbell and Mankiw(1987), Cochrane(1988, 1994), K ing et al.(1991), and Gal¶i(1996): what is t he relat ive import ance of permanent and t ransit ory shocks in explaining t he variat ion of macroeconomic dat a?

Our empirical ¯ ndings con¯ rm t he presence of common cycles in t he dat a. T he variance decomposit ion result s show t hat , for out put and invest ment , t ran-sit ory shocks are import ant in explaining t heir variat ion. On t he ot her hand, permanent shocks are t he most import ant source of variat ion for consumpt ion, whose behavior is close to a martingale (Hall(1978) and Flavin(1981)). Cont rast -ing our variance decomposit ion result s wit h t hose of K -ing et al.(1991), who only considered coint egrat ion rest rict ions t o ident ify permanent and t ransit ory shocks, illust rat es t hat ignoring common-cycle rest rict ions leads t o non-t rivial di®erences in t he relat ive import ance of t ransitory shocks. Indeed, we ¯ nd t ransit ory shocks t o be more import ant t han previous research has found. T his is t rue especially at business-cycle horizons, illust rat ing t he advant age of t he met hod used here. T hese ¯ ndings are consist ent wit h t he recent result s in Gal¶i(1996) - showing t hat nominal (t ransit ory) shocks are crit ical in explaining several feat ures of aggregat e dat a for G-7 count ries, and of den Haan(1996) - showing t hat demand shocks may be relevant for explaining t he condit ional correlat ions of out put and prices and of hours and real wages in t he short run.

(7)

t est ing for common t rends and cycles as well as t he est imat ion of dynamic sys-t ems under long- and shorsys-t -run co-movemensys-t ressys-t ricsys-t ions. A desys-t ailed explanasys-t ion of t he met hodology used is present ed in t he Appendix. Sect ion 4 present s empir-ical result s and Sect ion 5 concludes.

2. T heor y and Test abl e I m pl i cat i ons

Common t rends and common cycles appear in t he macroeconomics lit erat ure in several t heoret ical models. Here we discuss a few examples. In t he dynamic st ochast ic general equilibrium model of K ing, Plosser, and Rebelo(1988), out put , consumpt ion and invest ment have a common trend1and a common cycle as a re-sult of t he opt imizing behavior of t he represent at ive agent . Coint egrat ion comes from having a common forcing variable (product ivity) and a common cycle arises from t he fact t hat t he t ransit ional dynamics of t he syst em is a (linear) funct ion of a unique fact or - t he deviat ion of t he capit al st ock from it s st eady st at e value. Alt hough t hese result s are obt ained under log-ut ility, full-depreciat ion of t he cap-it al st ock, and Cobb-Douglas t echnology, t hey can be generalized for a variety of paramet erizat ions under a quadrat ic approximat ion of t he value funct ion. T he closed-form solut ions for t he logarithms of out put , consumpt ion and invest ment are respect ively:

log (Yt) = log (Xtp) + y + ¼ykkbt

log (Ct) = log (Xtp) + c + ¼ckkbt

log (It) = log (Xtp) + i + ¼i kkbt; (2.1)

where log (Xtp) = ¹ + log (X p t ¡ 1) + ²

p

t is t he random-walk product ivity process in

product ion, y, c and i are t he st eady-st ate values of log (Yt=Xtp); log (Ct=Xtp),

and log (It=Xtp) respect ively, and¼j k; j = y; c; i is t he elast icity of variable j wit h

respect t o deviat ions of t he capital st ock from it s st at ionary value

³ b

kt

´

2. From

1T he same result is t rue using t he endogenous growt h model of Romer(1986). T his makes

t hese two models observat ionally equivalent in coint egrat ing t est s.

2As not ed by K ing, Plosser and Rebelo(1988), t he above t heoret ical model is t oo simplist ic

t o be t aken as a full charact erizat ion of t he dat a-generat ing process, since it s only source of randomness is t he product ivity shock, making t he syst em in (2.1) st ochast ically singular. T here is an imbedded ident ity in t his syst em:

(¼i k¡ ¼ck) (log (Yt) ¡ y) = (¼i k ¡ ¼y k) (log (Ct) ¡ c) + (¼y k¡ ¼ck)

¡

log (It) ¡ i

(8)

(2.1) it is st raight forward t o verify t hat t hese variables have a common t rend (log (Xtp)), and a common cycle

³ b

kt

´

. T he following linear combinat ions have no t rend:

log (Yt) ¡ log (Ct)

log (Yt) ¡ log (It); (2.2)

and log (Yt), log (Ct), and log (It) are coint egrat ed in t he sense of Engle and

Granger(1987), wit h (2.2) showing two (linearly) independent coint egrat ing re-lat ionships. T he following linear combinat ions have no cycle:

¼cklog (Yt) ¡ ¼yk log (Ct)

¼i klog (Yt) ¡ ¼yk log (It); (2.3)

and log (Yt), log (Ct), and log (It) have a common cycle in t he sense of Vahid and

Engle(1993), wit h (2.3) showing two (linearly) independent cofeat ure combina-t ions.

To elaborat e more on t his issue, consider t he ¯ rst di®erences of t he logarit hm (i.e. growt h rat e) of t he syst em (2.1):

¢ log (Yt) = ²pt + ¼yk¢kbt

¢ log (Ct) = ²pt + ¼ck¢kbt

¢ log (It) = ²pt + ¼i k¢kbt: (2.4)

Given t hat ²pt is whit e noise, equat ions (2.4) show t hat all t he (short -run)

se-rial correlat ion of macroeconomic aggregat es is due t o a single common fact or

³

¢kbt

´

. T hus, \ cycles" in ¢ log (Yt), ¢ log (Ct), and ¢ log (It) are synchronized,

but amplit udes may di®er since t he¼j k's may be di®erent .

In t he class of part ial equilibrium models, Campbell(1987) shows t hat saving (St) can be writ t en as a funct ion of expect ed fut ure-income variat ionsEt(¢Yt + s):

St = ¡ 1

X

s= 1

½sEt(¢Yt+ s); (2.5)

whereEt is t he condit ional expect at ion operat or using informat ion up t o period

t, and ½is t he one-period discount fact or for fut ure income (Yt + s). Since saving

(9)

is st at ionary, consumpt ion and disposable income must coint egrat e if Yt is an

int egrat ed series.

For part ial equilibrium models in t he t radit ion of Hall(1978) and Flavin(1981), consumpt ion is a mart ingale. T hus, it s ¯ rst di®erence has no serial correlat ion even if t he (di®erenced) income process is serially correlat ed. T hus, consumpt ion and income fail t o have common cycles. However, if a proport ion of t he populat ion follows t he \ rule of t humb" of consuming t heir income ent irely in every period, Campbell and Mankiw(1989) show t hat aggregate consumpt ion and aggregat e income will have a common cycle as a result of t his myopic behavior.

Let t ing (C1t; Y1t) and (C2t; Y2t) be t he consumpt ion-income pairs of \

perma-nent income" and \ myopic" agent s respect ively, and let t ing (Ct; Yt) denot e t he

aggregat e consumpt ion-income pair, wit h ¸ = Y2t

Yt measuring t he income propor-t ion of myopic agenpropor-t s, Campbell and Mankiw show propor-t hapropor-t :

¢Ct = ¸ ¢ Yt + (1¡ ¸ ) ¹t; (2.6)

where¹t is proport ional t o t he innovat ion in Y1t. Since¹t is unpredict able, and

since ¢Yt is usually serially correlat ed, equat ion (2.6) shows t hat all t he serial

correlat ion of ¢Ct comes from ¢Yt. In t his case, t he cycles of Yt andCt are

syn-chronized. Not ice t hat t he amplit ude of t he cycle in consumpt ion is an increasing funct ion of t he import ance of myopic agent s (¸ ).

T he examples discussed above su± ce t o show t hat common t rends and com-mon cycles for macroeconomic aggregat es can be t he result of eit her opt imal or myopic behavior, and are a feat ure of part ial and general equilibrium models. T his in it self mot ivat es t heir invest igat ion. T here is an addit ional reason t o st udy t hem: common t rends and common cycles represent respect ively low- and high-frequency rest rict ions on mult ivariat e dat a set s. Whenever t hese rest rict ions are present , imposing t hem can considerably reduce t he number of est imat ed param-et ers in t ime series models, leading t o e± ciency gains in est imat ion.

3. Est im at i on and Test ing

(10)

Following K ing et al.(1991), it is useful t o not e t hat t he reduced form for a (lin-ear) syst em cont aining (t he log of ) out put , consumpt ion and invest ment is nest ed in t he general dynamic framework of Vect or Aut oregressions (VAR's). If t here are common trends in t he dat a, t he VAR has cross-equat ion rest rict ions as shown by Engle and Granger(1987). T hus, we can reduce t he number of paramet ers of t he dynamic represent at ion by est imat ing a Vect or Error-Correct ion Model (VECM) which t akes t hese rest rict ions int o account . Common cycles impose ext ra rest ric-t ions on ric-t his dynamic sysric-t em (Vahid and Engle(1993)). In ric-t his case iric-t is possible t o furt her reduce t he number of paramet ers in t he VECM. E± cient est imat ion requires est imating a rest rict ed VECM, which t akes int o account t he common cyclical dynamics present in t he ¯ rst di®erences of t he dat a; see equat ions (2.4) and (2.6) for example.

Test s for coint egrat ion are not discussed in any lengt h here, since t his lit erat ure is now well known. We employ Johansen's(1988, 1991) t echnique, which est imat es t he number of linearly independent coint egrating vect ors (r ). Test ing for common cycles amount s t o searching for independent linear combinat ions of t he (level of t he) variables t hat are random walks, t hus cycle free. T he t est t herefore is a search for linear combinat ions of t he ¯ rst di®erences of t he variables whose correlat ion wit h t he element s of t he past informat ion set in t he right -hand side of t he VECM will be zero. T his can be done by t est ing for zero canonical correlat ions between t he ¯ rst di®erences of t he variables and t he element s of t he past informat ion set . T his t est is in e®ect t est ing for cross-equat ion rest rict ions on t he paramet ers of t he VECM; see Vahid and Engle(1993).

Assuming t hat out put , consumpt ion and invest ment haveonest ochast ic t rend3, and that t he two coint egrat ing relat ionships are respect ively (log (Ct=Yt)) and

(log (It=Yt)), t he t est for common cycles and t he fully e± cient est imat ion of t he

rest rict ed VECM ent ails the following st eps:

1. Det erminep, t he required number of lags in t he VECM that adequat ely capt ures t he dynamics of t he syst em.

2. Comput e4 t he sample squared canonical correlat ions between

3T his is not t o say t hat t he common cycles t est is not applicable when variables have

de-t erminisde-t ic rade-t her de-t han sde-t ochasde-t ic de-t rends. In facde-t , common cycles are aboude-t co-movemende-t in det rended series, regardless of t he form of t he t rend. We explain t he procedure for t he case of st ochast ic t rends because it is more relevant t o t he present paper. T he case of det erminist ic t rend is st raight forward.

(11)

f¢ log (Yt); ¢ log (Ct); ¢ log (It)gand

flog (Ct ¡ 1=Yt ¡ 1); log (It ¡ 1=Yt¡ 1); ¢ log (Yt ¡ 1); ¢ log (Ct ¡ 1); ¢ log (It ¡ 1);

:::; ¢ log (Yt ¡ p); ¢ log (Ct ¡ p); ¢ log (It ¡ p)g, labelled ¸i, i = 1;¢¢¢; n, where

n is the number of variables in t he syst em (n equals t hree in t his case).

3. Test whet her t he¯ rst smallests canonical correlat ions are zero by comput ing t he st at ist ic:

¡ T

s

X

i = 1

log (1¡ ¸i);

which has a limit ing Â2 dist ribut ion wit h s (np + r )¡ s (n¡ s) degrees of

freedom under t he null, wherer is t he number of coint egrat ing relat ionships (r equals two in our example). In t he absence of ident it ies in t he syst em, t he maximum number of zero canonical correlat ions t hat can possibly exist isn¡ r (n¡ r is one in our example, since we assumed two coint egrat ing vect ors).

4. Suppose t hat s zero canonical correlat ions were found in t he previous st ep. Use t heses cont emporaneous relat ionships between t he ¯ rst di®erences as s pseudo-st ruct ural equat ions in a syst em of simult aneous equat ions. Aug-ment t hem wit h n¡ s equat ions from t he VECM and est imat e t he syst em using full informat ion maximum likelihood (FIML). T he rest rict ed VECM will be t he reduced form of t his pseudo-st ruct ural syst em.

In addit ion t o leading t o a parsimonious model, t he exist ence of unpredict able linear combinat ions of t he ¯ rst di®erences may allow us t o readily ident ify t he shocks wit h permanent e®ect s. Take, for example, t he model of K ing, Plosser, and Rebelo(1988) discussed above. T here,

¼ck¢ log (Yt) ¡ ¼yk¢ log (Ct) = (¼ck ¡ ¼yk)²pt

¼i k¢ log (Yt) ¡ ¼yk¢ log (It) = (¼i k ¡ ¼yk)²pt: (3.1)

Eit her of t hese two equat ions ident ify ²pt, given knowledge of ¼yk, ¼ck, and ¼i k.

Along t he same lines, for t he model of Campbell and Mankiw(1989), we have:

¢Ct ¡ ¸ ¢ Yt = (1¡ ¸ ) ¹t; (3.2)

(12)

which, given ¸ , ident i¯ es ¹t, t he shock t o permanent income of t he type one

consumer.

T his form of shock ident i¯ cat ion is much simpler t han t he met hod employed by K ing at al.(1991), since it only requires knowledge of cointegrat ing and cofea-t ure veccofea-t ors; see cofea-t he Appendix. T he lacofea-t cofea-t er requires invercofea-t ing cofea-t he aucofea-t oregressive represent at ion. Also, since we impose t est able long- and short -run rest rict ions to t he VAR, we achieve more e± cient est imat es of VAR coe± cient s. T his leads to more e± cient est imat es of impulse responses and variance decomposit ions, since t hese are based on a more parsimonious model.

It is import ant t o underst and t he possible di®erences in result s from using t he two met hods. If t he long-run rest rict ions imposed by bot h met hods are t he same, impulse-response and variance-decomposit ion result s will be similar for long horizons (being exactly t he same in t he in¯ nit e horizon). However, t hey have t he pot ent ial t o di®er at business-cycle horizons, since only t he met hod used here imposes short -run co-movement rest rict ions. Given t he e± ciency gains discussed above, our variance-decomposit ion and impulse-response result s will be more pre-cise at short horizons. As argued above, t his is import ant for economic agent s who discount fut ure event s more heavily, and t hus care more about what happens at business-cycle horizons. It is also import ant as a t ool in evaluat ing t heoret ical models in short horizons, especially regarding t he import ance of nominal shocks. Since t he e± ciency-gains result is t heoret ical, we compare out -of-sample fore-cast s between t he rest rict ed and the unrest rict ed VECM to subst ant iat e t hat t hese gains are relevant for t he present dat a set . We ¯ nd t hat t he former performs bet -t er.

4. Em pi r ical Ev idence

T he dat a being analyzed consist of (log) real U.S. per-capit a privat e out put - y, personal consumpt ion per-capit a - c, and ¯ xed invest ment per-capit a - i . T he dat a were ext ract ed from Cit ibase on a quart erly frequency5. Alt hough Cit ibase

has dat a available from 1947:1 t o 1994:2, we used only 1947:1 t hrough 1988:4 in est imat ion, in order t o mat ch t he sample period used in K ing et al.(1991), t hus making result s direct ly comparable.

5Using t he Cit ibase mnemonics (1995) for t he series, t he precise de¯ nit ions are: GCQ

(13)

T he plot of (logged) per-capit a real out put , consumpt ion and invest ment is present ed in Figure 1. T here are two st riking charact erist ics. First , t he data are ext remely smoot h (typical of I (1) dat a) and appear t o be t rending t oget her in t he long run. Second, t he dat a show similar short -run behavior: during recessions all t hree aggregat es drop. However, invest ment drops much more t han consumpt ion and out put , and t he lat t er drops more t han consumpt ion - t he most insensit ive series t o recessions.

Test s for coint egrat ion were performed using Johansen's(1988, 1991) t echnique and are present ed in Table 1. Crit ical values were ext ract ed from Ost erwald-Lenum(1992). We conclude t hat t he coint egrat ing rank r is two. T his implies t he exist ence of a common st ochastic t rend for out put , consumpt ion and invest ment . Table 1 also present s the point est imat es of a normalized version of t hese two vect ors. T hey are very close t o (¡ 1; 1; 0)0and (¡ 1; 0; 1)0respect ively, which implies t hat t he consumpt ion-out put and invest ment -out put rat ios areI (0). In order t o joint ly t est t hese hypot heses, we use t he likelihood ratio t est proposed in Johansen(1991). T he result s of t his t est do not reject t hat (¡ 1; 1; 0)0and (¡ 1; 0; 1)0are a basis for t he coint egrat ing space. T hese ¯ ndings are consistent wit h t he t heoret ical models ment ioned above, and with t he result s in K ing et al.(1991), who used a di®erent t est for coint egrat ion. T hey imply t hat t he \ great ratios" areI (0) processes.

T henext st ep of t he t est ing procedureis t o use canonical correlat ion analysis to examine whet her t he dat a have common cycles. For t he common-cycle t est , we use t he VECM wit h (¡ 1; 1; 0)0and (¡ 1; 0; 1)0as t he two coint egrat ing vect ors. We follow K ing et al.(1991) in condit ioning on eight lags of t he dependent variables in t he VECM, which is enough t o capt ure t he dynamics of t he syst em. Table 2 shows t he results of t he common-cycle t est s: t he p-values for t heÂ2 t est and it s F-t est

approximat ion6 of t he null hypot heses t hat t he current and all smaller canonical

correlat ions are st at ist ically zero. As not ed before, t he cofeat ure rank s is t he number of st at ist ically zero canonical correlat ions. At t he 5% level, bot h t est s cannot reject t he hypot hesis t hat t he smallest canonical correlat ion is st at ist ically zero, which implies t hat s is one. T hus, out put , consumpt ion and invest ment share two independent cycles and do have similar short -run ° uctuat ions.

As discussed in t he Appendix, t he fact t hat n = r + s allows a special t rend-cycle decomposit ion of t he dat a. Since we found a common st ochast ic t rend for our syst em, t he t rend component of out put , consumpt ion and invest ment

(14)

is t he same, being generat ed by t he linear combinat ion of t he dat a t hat uses t he cofeature vect or (t he maximum likelihood est imat e of t he common t rend is 0:42¢yt + 0:87¢ct ¡ 0:29¢it). On t he ot her hand, t hese variables will have cycles

t hat combine two distinct I (0) serially correlated component s, which are in t urn generat ed by t he linear combinat ions of t he dat a using t he coint egrat ing vect ors (t he great rat ios); see Table 3. Plot s of t he t rends and cycles of t he dat a are given in Figures 2 t hrough 4 and 5 t hrough 7 respect ively. T he t rend is very smoot h compared t o t he dat a in levels, and t he cycles show a dist inct pat t ern of serial correlat ion.

T hree feat ures are wort h not ing from t hese graphs: ¯ rst , it seems t hat t here is lit t le di®erence between consumpt ion and t he common t rend, which result s in a very small cycle for t hat variable (Cochrane(1994)). Alt hough consumpt ion cannot be charact erized as a random walk, t hus failing Hall's(1978) t est of t he permanent -income hypot hesis, it seems t hat it s cyclical component is very small7.

Similar result s are achieved by Fama(1992) and Cochrane(1994), alt hough wit h di®erent t echniques. Second, invest ment has a much more volat ile cycle t han out put and consumpt ion, which t ranslat es int o t he investment cycle having t he highest amplit ude of t hem all. T his is one of t he stylized fact s of business cycles cit ed in Lucas(1977). T hird, all t hree cycles drop during NBER recessions8.

T he est imat es of t rends and cycles of t he dat a allow us t o answer a quest ion considered import ant by most aut hors in t he applied macroeconomics lit erat ure: do permanent or t ransit ory shocks explain t he bulk of t he variance of aggregat e dat a? At t empt s t o answer t his quest ion can be found, among ot hers, in t he work of Nelson and Plosser(1982), Wat son(1986), Campbell and Mankiw(1987), Cochrane(1988, 1994), K ing et al.(1991), and Gal¶i(1996). Nelson and Plosser ¯ nd t his issue import ant because t hey associat e t rends t o permanent fact ors in° u-encing out put - such as product ivity, and cycles t o t ransit ory fact ors - such as monet ary policy.

Since t he t rend-innovat ion e®ect s are permanent while t he cycle-innovat ion e®ect s are only t ransit ory, it seems reasonable t o at t ach import ance t o t he t rend component if t he t rend innovat ion explains a signi¯ cant proport ion of t ot al fore-cast errors at business-cycle horizons. T he result s of t he variance decomposit ion of

7We ret urn t o t his issue lat er, aft er present ing t he result s of t he variance decomposit ion of

innovat ions of t he dat a set .

8Some minor except ions are veri¯ ed. T he t rend somet imes drops during recessions as well,

(15)

out put , consumpt ion and invest ment are present ed in Table 4. T his t able shows t he percent age of t he variance of t ot al forecast errors explained by permanent shocks at di®erent horizons9. For out put , t ransit ory shocks explain about 50% of t he forecast error variance (FEV) at t he two year horizon, more t han 40% at t he three-year horizon, and more t han 30% at t he four-year horizon. For short er horizons, t ransit ory shocks explain more t han half of t he FEV. In t hat sense, we cannot discard t he import ance of t he t ransit ory component of out put . T he result s for invest ment are much st ronger. Transit ory shocks explain most of t he FEV for all t abulat ed ¯ nit e horizons. For t he one-year horizon, t hese shocks explain more t han 90% of t he FEV, and for t he two-year horizon almost 80%.

T he result s of t he variance decomposit ion for consumpt ion allow discussing t he permanent -income hypot hesis. At t he one-year horizon, the permanent com-ponent explains almost 80% of t he FEV, and at t he two-year horizon about 85%. T he pict ure t hat emerges is t hat of an all-import ant permanent component . T he plot of Figure 3 corroborat es t his evidence. On t he one hand, if one is willing to label t he permanent part of consumpt ion as permanent income10, t he

variance-decomposit ion analysis allows one t o conclude t hat permanent income is by far t he most import ant component of consumpt ion. Moreover, consumpt ion and per-manent income obey long-run proport ionality, an import ant t heoret ical result . On t he ot her hand, although we found excess sensit ivity in consumpt ion, e.g., Hall(1978) and Flavin(1981), consumpt ion's t ransit ory part has very lit t le impor-t ance.

At t his point , it is useful t o compare t he result of our variance decomposit ion wit h t hose of K ing et al.(1991). Since bot h st udies used t he same dat a and sample period, t he result s are direct ly comparable and any di®erences in result s can be at tribut ed t o short -run co-movement rest rict ions being imposed by our met hod.

9Trend innovat ions are t he ¯ rst di®erences of t he common t rend. Cycle innovat ions are

t he residuals obt ained by regressing cycles on t he right -hand-side variables in t he VECM (t he lagged error-correct ion t erms and t he eight ¯ rst lags of t he dependent variables). Since t he two innovat ions are correlat ed, we ort hogonalize t hem, and we denot e t he port ion of t he cycle innovat ion ort hogonal t o t he t rend innovat ion as t he \ t ransit ory shock" . T he \ permanent shock" will t hen comprise t he original t rend innovat ion and t he port ion of t he cycle innovat ion explained by t he t rend innovat ion.

10According t o one view of t he permanent -income hypot hesis, consumpt ion should be equal t o

(16)

K ing et al. result s are reported in parent heses in Table 4. As expect ed, t he major di®erences in result s occur for short horizons (1-12 quart ers): t heir met hod under-est imat es t he cont ribut ion of t he t ransit ory port ion of out put and invunder-est ment . T he same happens for consumpt ion for t he 1-t o-4-quart er horizon, being reversed, however, for longer horizons. T he biggest discrepancy happens for out put : in t heir met hod, t he permanent port ion of out put explains almost 60% (70%) of out put variance for t he one-(two-)year horizon, whereas our result assigns about 40% (50%) t o it . T hese di®erences are enough t o change t he emphasis of t he variance decomposit ion result s for out put . It is clear t hat a much more considerable role should be at t ribut ed t o sources of t ransit ory noise. It is import ant t o not e t hat t his result was obt ained in a framework where only real variables were considered, which in it self pot ent ially limit s t he role of some sources of t ransit ory shocks, e.g., monet ary policy; see t he result s in K ing et al.(1991) when monet ary variables are included in t he VAR and also t he discussion in Hansen and Heckman(1996, foot not e 9).

T he import ance of t ransit ory component s of out put was also report ed by Cochrane(1994), and a similar general result is achieved by King et al.(1991), aft er augment ing t heir VAR wit h monet ary-sector variables. More recent ly, Gal¶i(1996) has shown t hat nominal (non-permanent ) shocks are critical for explaining t he condit ional correlat ion pat t ern of labor product ivity and employment (or hours). Moreover, t hese nominal shocks are responsible for t he synchronized cyclical be-havior of GDP and hours: when t he nominal-shock component s of GDP and hours are ignored, t hese two series fail t o show any dist inct business-cycle pat t ern (see Gal¶i's Figure 6). Along t he same lines, den Haan(1996) ¯ nds t hat out put and prices are positively correlat ed at business-cycle horizons, alt hough negat ively correlat ed in t he long run. T his support s t he conclusion t hat nominal shocks are import ant in t he short run while real shocks are import ant in t he long run. It also illust rat es t hat t he horizon mat t ers for invest igat ing t he plausibility of di®erent t heories, a point also st ressed by Hansen and Heckman(1996).

T his body of evidence goes against t he claim in Nelson and Plosser(1982) t hat permanent shocks are t he most import ant source of variat ion for out put . Alt hough t here is no doubt t hat t his is t rue for long horizons, result s for business-cycle horizons point t owards t he import ance of t ransit ory shocks. If t he horizon mat t ers, it would be int erest ing t o consider t he most precise t echnique at short horizons, and t his is exact ly what we have t ried t o provide in t his paper.

(17)

nominal shocks at business-cycle horizons, it is not obvious how t o int erpret t he evidence. T heoret ical models are rarely built in t erms of permanent or t ransi-t ory shocks. Raransi-t her, ransi-t hey are builransi-t in ransi-t erms of real (producransi-t iviransi-ty) or nominal (monet ary) shocks. T hus, t o t est t heories, one has usually t o impose ident ifying assumpt ions. For example, Blanchard and Quah(1989), K ing et al. (t ri-variat e syst em), and Gal¶i assume t hat t he only source of permanent shocks is produc-t iviproduc-ty. Non-permanenproduc-t shocks are labelled \ demand" shocks by Blanchard and Quah and Gal¶i. However, one can cert ainly t hink of permanent demand shocks (a permanent change in preferences, for example) or of t ransit ory supply shocks (t ransit ory t echnology shocks, for example). In these cases t hose ident ifying as-sumpt ions will fail11.

Alt hough answering t hese issues is out of t he scope of t his paper, we argue t hat t he result s here and elsewhere are st ill useful. We rely on t he reasonable assumpt ion t hat permanent shocks are more likely to be real, whereas t ransit ory shocks are more likely t o be nominal. T his \ axiom," as far as we know, has never been openly challenged, despit e t he fact t hat more t han 15 years have now elapsed since Nelson and Plosser ¯ rst used it .

4.1. Post -Sample For ecast s of Per -C api t a Out put , C onsum pt ion and I nvest m ent

T his last sect ion compares post -sample forecast s of two economet ric represent a-t ions of our a-t ri-variaa-t e sysa-t em. T he ¯ rsa-t is a-t he Unresa-t rica-t ed VECM (UVECM), which does not t ake int o account short -run rest rict ions implied by t he exist ence of common cycles. T he second is t he Restrict ed VECM (RVECM), which t akes t hose rest rict ions int o account . Sample est imat es used dat a for out put , consump-t ion, and invesconsump-t menconsump-t from 1947:1 consump-t o 1988:4. Posconsump-t -sample one-sconsump-t ep-ahead forecasconsump-t s for each represent at ion were t hen calculat ed from 1989:1 t o 1994:2, comprising 22 quart erly observat ions.

Est imat ion of t he UVECM used eight lags for all lagged dependent variables and one lag for t he error-correct ion t erms. Since it is a reduced-form, it was est imat ed by Least Squares. T he RVECM was estimat ed using t he same lag st ruct ure as the UVECM, but imposing common-cycle rest rict ions on t he syst em.

11T his, however, is not t he only problem. In an economy wit h dist ort ions, Basu and

(18)

As discussed in t he Appendix, t hese rest rict ions can be convenient ly formulat ed in t erms of exclusion rest rict ions in a syst em of \ st ruct ural"12 equat ions. T hus, t he

syst em was est imat ed using FIML, a suit able met hod for est imat ing st ruct ural forms, t o ¯ nd t he maximum likelihood est imat es of t he paramet ers.

Forecast ing result s are reported in Table 5, which cont ains t he mean squared error (MSE) in forecast for each equat ion separat ely, and t he determinant of t he mean squared forecast error mat rix, a measure of t he overall forecast ing perfor-mance for t he syst em.

For t he overall syst em, it is clear t hat t he RVECM represent at ion does bet t er, wit h a di®erence in t he det erminant of t he mean squared forecast error mat rix of more t han 25%. For individual equat ions, t he RVECM out performs t he UVECM in forecast ing for all t hree series. T he forecast ing improvement is most remark-able for out put and consumpt ion. T he empirical result s achieved here con¯ rms t he t heoret ical predict ion t hat rest rict ed est imat ion reduces MSE whenever \ t rue rest rict ions" are imposed on est imat ion.

5. Concl usi ons

T his paper con¯ rms t he predict ion of several t heoret ical models t hat out put , consumpt ion and invest ment share bot h a common t rend and common cycles. Alt hough common t rends have been invest igat ed and con¯ rmed before, ¯ nding common cycles const it ut es new evidence regarding t his aggregat e dat a set . As discussed above, t his ¯ nding is relevant for calculat ing more precisely t he relat ive import ance of permanent and t ransit ory shocks at business-cycle horizons, for which t his issue is st ill cont roversial and which economic agent s ¯ nd more relevant for welfare considerat ions.

T he result s show t hat t ransit ory shocks are more import ant t han previously t hought . T hey explain about 50% of t he variat ion of out put at t he 2-year horizon, more t han 40% at t he 3-year horizon, and more t han 30% at t he 4-year horizon. T he result s for invest ment are even st ronger: more t han 50% up t o t he 5-year horizon. Despit e t hese result s, t he permanent shock explains a very large pro-port ion of consumpt ion variat ion, providing evidence of consumpt ion smoot hing over t ime. T he import ance of t ransit ory shocks document ed here ¯ nds support in t he recent research by Gal¶i(1996) and den Haan(1996), as well as in t he work

(19)

of Cochrane(1994). It may be a sign t hat nominal shocks are relevant for t he short -run variat ions of macroeconomic dat a.

Finally, by using a post-sample forecast ing exercise, t his paper est ablishes t hat ignoring common-cycle rest rict ions in t his mult ivariat e dat a set can lead t o a non-t rivial loss of e± ciency in est imat ing reduced-form VECM's. T his can a®ect t he precision of est imat es of t rends and cycles, as well as t he precision of impulse-response and variance-decomposit ion exercises. T herefore, t est ing for common cycles should always precede economet ric est imat ion whenever short -run co-movement rest rict ions are likely t o be present .

R efer ences

[1] Basu, S. and Fernald, J.(1997), \ Aggregat e Product ivity and Aggregat eTech-nology," Working Paper: University of Michigan.

[2] Beveridge, S. and Nelson, C.R.(1981), \ A New Approach t o Decomposit ion of Economic T ime Series int o a Permanent and Transit ory Component s wit h Part icular At t ent ion t o Measurement of t he \ Business Cycle" , Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 7, pp. 151-174.

[3] Blanchard, O.J. and Quah, D.(1989), \ T he Dynamic E®ect s of Aggregat e Supply and Demand Dist urbances" , American Economic Review, vol. 79, pp. 655-673.

[4] Campbell, J.Y.(1987), \ Does Saving Ant icipat e Declining Labor Income? An Alternat ive Test of t he Permanent Income Hypot hesis," Econometrica, vol. 55(6), pp. 1249-73.

[5] Campbell, J.Y. and Mankiw, N.G.(1987), \ Permanent and Transit ory Com-ponent s in Macroeconomic Fluct uat ions" , American Economic Review.

[6] Campbell, J.Y. and Mankiw, N.G.(1989), \ Consumpt ion, Income and Int er-est Rat es: Reint erpret ing the T ime Series Evidence," NBER Macroeconomics Annual.

(20)

[8] Cochrane, J.H.(1994), \ Permanent and Transit ory Component s of GNP and Stock Prices," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 30, pp. 241-265.

[9] den Haan, W.(1996), \ T he Comovements Between Real Act ivity and Prices at Di®erent Business Cycle Frequencies," Working Paper: University of Cal-ifornia, San Diego.

[10] Engle, R.F. and Granger, C.W.J.(1987), \ Coint egrat ion and Error Correc-t ion: RepresenCorrec-t aCorrec-t ion, EsCorrec-t imaCorrec-t ion and TesCorrec-t ing," Econometrica, vol. 55, pp. 251-276.

[11] Engle, R.F. and K ozicki, S.(1993), \ Test ing for Common Feat ures," Journal of Business and Economic St at ist ics, vol. 11, pp. 369-395, wit h discussions.

[12] Engle, R.F. and Issler, J.V.(1995), \ Est imating Common Sect oral Cycles" , Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 35, pp. 83-113.

[13] Engle, R.F. and Yoo, B.S.(1987), \ Forecast ing and Test ing in Coint egrat ed Syst ems," Journal of Econometrics, vol. 35, pp. 143-159.

[14] Fama, E.(1992), \ Transit ory Variat ion in Invest ment and Out put " , Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 30, pp. 467-480.

[15] Flavin, M.A.(1981), \ T he adjust ment of Consumpt ion t o Changing Expec-t aExpec-t ion abouExpec-t FuExpec-t ure Income" , Journal of Political Economy, vol. 89(5), pp. 974-1009.

[16] Gal¶i, J.(1996), \ Technology, Employment and t he Business Cycle: Do Tech-nology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluct uat ions?" NBER Working Paper # 5721.

[17] Hall, R.E.(1978), \ St ochast ic Implicat ions of t he Life Cycle-Permanent In-come Hypot hesis: T heory and Evidence," Journal of Political Economy, 86, pp. 971-987.

[18] Hansen, L.P. and Heckman, J.J.(1996), \ T he Empirical Foundat ions of Cal-ibrat ion" Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol., 10(1), pp. 87-104.

(21)

[20] Johansen, S.(1991), \ Est imation and Hypot hesis Test ing of Coint egrat ion Vect ors in Gaussian Vect or Aut oregressive Models," Econometrica, vol. 59, pp. 1551-1580.

[21] K ing, R.G., Plosser, C.I. and Rebelo, S.(1988), \ Product ion, Growt h and Business Cycles. I I. New Direct ions," Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 21, pp. 309-341.

[22] K ing, R.G., Plosser, C.I., St ock, J.H. and Wat son, M.W.(1991), \ St ochast ic Trends and Economic Fluct uat ions," American Economic Review, vol. 81, pp. 819-840.

[23] K osobud, R. and K lein, L.(1961), \ Some Economet rics of Growt h: Great Rat ios of Economics," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 25, 173-198.

[24] Lucas, R.E.,Jr.(1977), \ Underst anding Business Cycles," Carnegie-Rochest er Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 5, pp. 7-29. Amst erdam: Nort h Hol-land.

[25] Nelson, C.R. and Plosser, C.I.(1982), \ Trends and Random Walks in Macroe-conomic T ime Series," Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 10, pp. 139-162.

[26] Ost erwald-Lenum, M.(1992), Quant iles of t he Asympt otic Dist ribut ion of t he Maximum Likelihood Coint egration Rank Test St at ist ics," Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, vol. 54, 461-472.

[27] Rao, C.R.(1973), \Linear Statistical I nference" , New York: Wiley.

[28] Romer, P. (1986), \ Increasing Ret urns and Long Run Growt h," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94, pp. 1002-1037.

[29] Vahid, F. and Engle, R.F.(1993), \ Common Trends and Common Cycles," Journal of Applied Econometrics, vol. 8, pp. 341-360.

[30] Vahid, F. and Engle, R.F.(1997), \ Codependent Cycles," Journal Economet-rics, vol. 80, pp. 199-121.

(22)

A . C o-M ovem ent R est r i ct i ons in D ynam i c M odel s

Before discussing t he dynamic represent at ion of t he dat a, and t he t rend-cycle de-composit ion met hod we have used, we present t he de¯ nit ions of common t rends and common cycles. For a full discussion see Engle and Granger(1987) and Vahid and Engle(1993) respect ively. First , we assume t hat yt is an-vector of I (1)

vari-ables, wit h t he st at ionary (M A (1 )) Wold represent at ion given by:

¢ yt = C (L ) ²t; (A.1)

where C (L ) is a mat rix polynomial in t he lag operat or, L , wit h C (0) = In, 1

P

j = 1

kCjk< 1 . T he vect or ²t is an£ 1 vect or of st at ionary one-st ep-ahead linear

forecast errors inyt; given informat ion on t he lagged values of yt. We can rewrit e

equat ion (A.1) as:

¢ yt = C (1) ²t + ¢C¤(L ) ²t (A.2)

whereC¤ i =

P

j > i

¡ Cj for all i : In part icular C0¤= In¡ C (1).

If we int egrat e bot h sides of equat ion (A.2) we get :

yt = C (1) 1

X

s= 0

²t ¡ s+ C¤(L ) ²t

= Tt + Ct (A.3)

Equat ion (A.3) is t he mult ivariat e version of t he Beveridge-Nelson t rend-cycle represent at ion (Beveridge and Nelson(1981)). T he series yt are represent ed as

sum of a random walk part Tt which is called t he \ t rend" and a st at ionary part

Ct which is called t he \ cycle" .

D e¯ ni t i on A .1. T he variables in yt are said t o have common t rends (or

coin-t egracoin-t e) if coin-t here arer linearly independent vect ors, r < n, st acked in an r £ n mat rix ®0, wit h t he property t hat :

®0

r £ n C (1) = 0:

D e¯ ni t i on A .2. T he variables in yt are said to have common cycles if t here are

s linearly independent vect ors, s· n¡ r , st acked in an s£ n mat rix ~®0, wit h t he

property t hat :

~ ®0

s£ n C

(23)

T hus, coint egrat ion and common cycles represent rest rict ions on t he element s of C (1) and C¤(L ) respect ively.

We now discuss rest rict ions on t he dynamic autoregressive represent at ion of economic t ime series arising from coint egrat ion (common t rends) and common cycles. First, we assume t hat yt is generat ed by a Vect or Aut oregression (VAR):

yt = ¡1yt¡ 1+ : : : + ¡pyt ¡ p+ ²t (A.4)

If element s of yt coint egrat e, t hen t he mat rix I ¡ p

P

i = 1¡i must have less t han

full rank, which imposes cross-equat ion rest rict ions on t he VAR. In t his case, Engle and Granger(1987) show t hat t he syst em (A.4) can be writ t en as a Vect or Error-Correct ion model (VECM):

¢ yt = ¡ ¤1¢ yt¡ 1+ : : : + ¡p¡ 1¤ ¢ yt ¡ p+ 1+ ° ®0yt ¡ 1+ ²t (A.5)

where° and ® are full rank mat rices of order n£ r , r is t he rank of t he coint e-grat ing space, I ¡ Pp

i = 1

¡i = ° ®0, and ¡¤j = ¡ p

P

i = j + 1

¡i , j = 1; : : : ; p¡ 1. Given t he

cointegrat ing vect ors st acked in ®0, it can be seen t hat (A.5) parsimoniously

en-compasses (A.4). Conditional on knowledge of coint egrat ing vect ors, t he VECM hasn2(p¡ 1) + n¢r paramet ers in t he condit ional mean, while t he VAR has n2¢p

paramet ers. T hus, the former hasn¢(n¡ r ) fewer paramet ers, since r < n. If we t ake into account t he free parameters in t he coint egrat ing vect or, t he VECM has n2(p¡ 1) + 2n¢r ¡ r2 mean paramet ers, (n¡ r )2

fewer t han t he VAR.

Vahid and Engle(1993) show t hat t he dynamic represent at ion of t he dat a yt

may have additional cross-equat ion rest rict ions if t here are common cycles. To see t his, recall t hat t he cofeat ure vect ors ~®0i, st acked in an s£ n mat rix ~®0,

elim-inat e all serial correlat ion in ¢ yt; i.e. ~®0¢ yt = ~®0²t. Since t he cofeat ure vect ors

are ident i¯ ed only up t o an invert ible t ransformat ion, we can, wit hout loss of generality, rot at e ~® t o have an s dimensional ident ity sub-mat rix:

~ ® = " In ~ ®¤

(n¡ s)£ s

#

Considering ~®0¢ y

t = ~®0²t ass equat ions in a syst em, and complet ing t he syst em

(24)

of ¢ yt; we obt ain,

2

4 Is ®~

¤0

0

(n ¡ s)£ s In¡ s

3

5¢ yt = 2

4 s£ (n p+ r )0

¡¤¤

1 : : : ¡¤¤p¡ 1 °¤

3 5 2 6 6 6 6 4

¢ yt¡ 1

.. . ¢ yt ¡ p+ 1

®0yt¡ 1

3 7 7 7 7

5 + vt; (A.6)

where ¡ ¤¤

i and°¤ represent t he part it ions of ¡¤i and° respect ively, corresponding

t o t he bot t omn¡ s reduced form VECM equat ions, and vt =

2

4 Is ®~

¤0

0

(n ¡ s)£ s In¡ s

3 5 ²

t:

It is easy t o show t hat (A.6) parsimoniously encompasses (A.5). Since

2

4 Is ®~

¤0

0

(n ¡ s)£ s In¡ s

3

5 is invert ible, it is possible t o recover (A.5) from (A.6). Not ice

however t hat t he lat t er hass ¢(np + r )¡ s¢(n¡ s) fewer paramet ers.

B . Tr end-Cy cl e D ecom p osi t i on

We now discuss t he t rend-cycle decomposit ion used here. For a full discussion see Vahid and Engle(1993). From equat ion(A.3):

yt = C (1) 1

X

s= 0

²t ¡ s + C¤(L ) ²t (B.1)

= Tt + Ct

Consider t he special case of n = r + s; and st ack t he cofeat ure and t he coin-t egracoin-t ing combinacoin-t ions coin-t o obcoin-t ain,

"

~ ®0y

t

®0y t

#

=

"

~ ®0T

t

®0C t

#

: (B.2)

T hen£ n mat rix A =

"

~ ®0

®0

#

has full rank and t herefore is invert ible. Part

i-t ion i-t he columns of i-t he inverse accordingly asA¡ 1 = [ ~®¡ ®¡ ] and recover t he common-t rend common-cycle decomposit ion by pre-mult iplying t he cofeat ure and cointegrat ing combinat ions by A¡ 1:

(25)

T his implies t hat Tt = ~®¡ ®~0yt andCt = ®¡ ®0yt, i.e. t rends and cycles are simple

linear combinat ions of t he dat ayt.

(26)

TABLE 1

COINTEGRATING RESULTS USING JOHANSEN’S(1988) TECHNIQUE

EIGENVALUES

( )

µi

TRACE TEST

(

)

− − ≤

T j j i

ln 1 µ

CRITICAL VALUE

AT 5%

NULL HYPOTHESES

0.01886 3.06 3.76 ∃ at most 2

cointegrating vectors

0.07726 16.01 15.41 ∃ at most 1

cointegrating vectors

0.13944 40.18 29.68 ∃ at most 0

cointegrating vectors

Estimated Normalized Cointegrating Space:

$ . . ′ =−     

α 1 06 1 0

101 0 1

Test of Restrictions in the Cointegrating Space:

H0 1 1 0

1 0 1

: ′ = − −     α

( )

χ2

(27)

TABLE 2

CANONICAL CORRELATION ANALYSIS COMMON-CYCLE TESTS

SQUARED CANONICAL

CORRELATIONS

( )

λi

2

Prob> χ2

( )

d (d)

Prob.>F NULL HYPOTHESES

0.4892 >0.0001

(78)

0.0001 Current and all smaller

( )

λ

i are zero

0.2860 0.004

(50)

0.0226 Current and all smaller

( )

λ

i are zero

0.1544 0.3200

(24)

0.4651 Current and all smaller

( )

λ

i are zero

TABLE 3

TRENDS AND CYCLES AS LINEAR COMBINATIONS OF THE DATAa

TRENDS

VARIABLE Y c i

y 0.42 0.87 -0.29

c 0.42 0.87 -0.29

i 0.42 0.87 -0.29

CYCLES

VARIABLE y c i

y 0.58 -0.87 0.30

c -0.42 0.13 0.30

i -0.42 -0.87 1.30

(28)

TABLE 4

COMPARING RESULTS OF VARIANCE DECOMPOSITION OF INNOVATIONS:

% OF THE VARIANCE ATTRIBUTED TO THE PERMANENT INNOVATION FOR: (KING ET AL. RESULTS IN PARENTHESIS) HORIZON

(QUARTERS)

OUTPUT CONSUMPTION INVESTMENT

1 32.1 (45.0) 64.8 (88.0) 0.0 (12.0) 4 37.4 (58.0) 77.1 (89.0) 9.0 (31.0) 8 50.7 (68.0) 85.3 (83.0) 20.8 (40.0) 12 57.5 (73.0) 88.2 (83.0) 24.9 (43.0) 16 66.7 (77.0) 90.4 (85.0) 35.0 (44.0) 20 76.1 (79.0) 92.5 (87.0) 44.6 (46.0) ∞ 100.0 (100.0) 100.0 (100.0) 100.0 (100.0)

(29)

TABLE 5

POST-SAMPLE FORECASTING RESULTS FOR THE RVECM AND UVECM REPRESENTATIONS

MEAN SQUARED ERROR (MSE)

DEPENDENT VARIABLE

RVECM UVECM

y 0.5079 0.6099

c 0.5000 0.5889

i 3.6503 3.6772

(30)
(31)
(32)
(33)
(34)
(35)
(36)

Referências

Documentos relacionados

The presence of t hese at ypical cases could be more frequent t han previously expect ed and w e reinforce t hat t he DNA met hylat ion analysis is import ant for t he correct

Moreover, “[t]he further development of security and defence cooperation to live up to the Union’s commitments and responsibilities across the world by strengthening the

The idea of act ive isom or phism does not cont radict t he t radit ional defi nit ion of isom or phism ; rat her, t his idea adds t he dialogism and r ecur- siveness of t he

Archiv der Kolonie M enno, Loma Plat a, Paraguay... This w as t he era of cent ralized planning agencies like t he Tennessee Valley Aut horit y in t he Unit ed St at es and of

The opinions expressed in t his art icle are t he sole responsabilit y of t he aut hors and do not in any way represent t he posit ion of t he organizat ion t hey work at or it s

Un det ect ed in fect ion is t he more common scen ario... A risk of min

In a clin ical t rial in Can ada, t he effect iven ess of INH alone and in combination with para-aminosalicylic acid (PAS) in t he preven t ion of TB react ivat ion was est imat

It is described t hat “ t he clinical consequence of radiculopat hy is arm pain or parest hesia in t he derm at omal dist ribut ion of t he af fect ed nerve and m ay or